Degrowth is an academic and social movement critical of the concept of growth in gross domestic product as a measure of human and economic development.[1][2][3][4][5][6][7][8] Degrowth theory is based on ideas and research from a multitude of disciplines such as economics, economic anthropology, ecological economics, environmental sciences and development studies. It argues that the unitary focus of modern capitalism on growth, in terms of monetary value of aggregate goods and services, causes widespread ecological damage and is not necessary for the further increase of human living standards.[9][10][11] Degrowth theory has been met with both academic acclaim and considerable criticism.[12][13][14]

Degrowth theory's main argument is that an infinite expansion of the economy is fundamentally contradictory to the finiteness of material resources on Earth. It argues that economic growth measured by GDP should be abandoned as a policy objective. Policy should instead focus on economic and social metrics such as life expectancy, health, education, housing, and ecologically sustainable work as indicators of both eco-systems and human well-being.[15] Degrowth theorists posit that this may increase human living standards and ecological preservation, even while GDP slows down or decreases.[16][17][18]

Degrowth theory is highly critical of free market capitalism, and it highlights the importance of extensive public services, care work, self-organization, commons, relational goods, community, and work sharing.[19][20]

Background edit

The "degrowth" movement arose from concerns over the consequences of the productivism and consumerism associated with industrial societies (whether capitalist or socialist) including:[21]

In 2017, Inês Cosme and colleagues summarised the research literature on degrowth, finding that it focused on three main goals: (1) reduction of environmental degradation; (2) redistribution of income and wealth locally and globally; (3) promotion of a social transition from economic materialism to participatory culture.[22] In 2022, Nick Fitzpatrick and colleagues surveyed 1,166 research publications on degrowth, and found 530 specific policy proposals with "50 goals, 100 objectives, 380 instruments", arguing that their survey constituted "the most exhaustive degrowth policy agenda ever presented".[23] Degrowth research was active in the 2010s in the work of Joan Martinez-Alier and the "Barcelona School".[24]

Decoupling edit

The concept of decoupling denotes the possibility to decouple economic growth, usually measured in GDP growth, from the use of natural resources and greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. Absolute decoupling refers to GDP growth coinciding with a reduction in natural resource use and GHG emissions, while relative decoupling describes an increase in resource use and GHG emission lower than the increase in GDP growth.[25] The degrowth movement heavily critiques this idea and argues that absolute decoupling is only possible for short periods, specific locations or with small mitigation rates.[26][27] A 2021 publication by the European Environmental Bureau called "Decoupling Debunked: Evidence and arguments against green growth as a sole strategy for sustainability" analyzed a large amount of empirical and theoretical work on the topic and stated that:

"not only is there no empirical evidence supporting the existence of a decoupling of economic growth from environmental pressures on anywhere near the scale needed to deal with environmental breakdown, but also, and perhaps more importantly, such decoupling appears unlikely to happen in the future". (page 3).[27]

Further, the paper states that reported cases of "successful" decoupling either depict relative decoupling and/or are observed only temporarily and/or only on a local scale.[27] This is supported by several other studies which state that absolute decoupling is highly unlikely to be achieved fast enough to prevent global warming over 1.5 °C or 2 °C, even under optimistic policy conditions.[28] Moreover, relying on decoupling as the main or only strategy to combine economic growth and the reduction of environmental pressures would be a high-risk action in the context of the climate emergency of the 21st century.[26] Consequently, degrowth advocates argue that alternatives to decoupling are needed.

Resource depletion edit

As economies grow, the need for resources grows accordingly (unless there are changes in efficiency or demand for different products due to price changes).[citation needed] There is a fixed supply of non-renewable resources, such as petroleum (oil), and these resources can be depleted. Renewable resources can also be depleted if extracted at unsustainable rates over extended periods. This has already occurred, for example, with caviar production in the Caspian Sea.[29]

Degrowth proponents argue that decreasing demand is the only way to close the demand gap permanently. For renewable resources, demand and production must also be brought down to levels that prevent depletion and are environmentally sustainable. Moving toward a society not dependent on oil is essential to avoiding societal collapse when non-renewable resources are depleted.[30] Degrowth can also be seen as a call for resource shifting where one strives to put an end to the unsustainable social processes of turning things into resources, for example non-renewable natural resources, and turn instead other things into resources, for example, renewable human resources.[31]

Ecological footprint edit

The ecological footprint measures human demand on the Earth's ecosystems. It compares human demand with the Earth's ecological capacity to regenerate. It represents the amount of biologically productive land and sea area needed to regenerate the resources a human population consumes and to absorb and render harmless the corresponding waste.

According to a 2005 Global Footprint Network report,[32] inhabitants of high-income countries live off of 6.4 global hectares (gHa), while those from low-income countries live off of a single gHa. For example, while each inhabitant of Bangladesh lives off of what they produce from 0.56 gHa, a North American requires 12.5 gHa. Each inhabitant of North America uses 22.3 times as much land as a Bangladeshi. According to the same report, the average number of global hectares per person was 2.1, while current consumption levels have reached 2.7 hectares per person. In order for the world's population to attain the living standards typical of European countries, the resources of between three and eight planet Earths would be required with current levels of efficiency and means of production. For world economic equality to be achieved with the currently available resources, proponents say rich countries would have to reduce their standard of living through degrowth. The constraints on resources would eventually lead to a forced reduction in consumption. Controlled reduction of consumption would reduce the trauma of this change, assuming no technological changes increase the planet's carrying capacity. Multiple studies now demonstrate that in many affluent countries per-capita energy consumption could be decreased substantially and quality living standards still be maintained.[33]

Degrowth and sustainable development edit

Degrowth thought is in opposition to all forms of productivism (the belief that economic productivity and growth are the purposes of human organization). It is, thus, opposed to the current form of sustainable development.[34] While the concern for sustainability does not contradict degrowth, sustainable development is rooted in mainstream development ideas that aim to increase economic growth and consumption. Degrowth therefore sees sustainable development as an oxymoron,[35] as any development based on growth in a finite and environmentally stressed world is seen as inherently unsustainable. Critics of degrowth argue that a slowing of economic growth would result in increased unemployment, increased poverty, and decreased income per capita. Many who understand the devastating environmental consequences of growth still advocate for economic growth in the South, even if not in the North. But, slowing economic growth would fail to deliver the benefits of degrowth—self-sufficiency, material responsibility—and would indeed lead to decreased employment. Rather, degrowth proponents advocate the complete abandonment of the current (growth) economic model, suggesting that relocalizing and abandoning the global economy in the Global South would allow people of the South to become more self-sufficient and would end the overconsumption and exploitation of Southern resources by the North.[35] Proponents of degrowth see it as a possible path to preserve ecosystems from human pressures. In this idea, the environment is communally cared for, integrating humans and nature; degrowth implies the perception of ecosystems as inherently valuable, not just as a source of resources.[21] At the Second International Conference on degrowth, ideas such as a maximum wage and open borders were discussed. Degrowth suggests a deontological shift so that lifestyles that involve a high level of resource consumption are no longer seen as attractive. Other visions of degrowth include the global North repairing past injustices from centuries of colonization and exploitation and redistributing wealth, and a concept of the appropriate scale of action is a major topic of debate within degrowth movements.[21]

Some researchers believe that the world will have to pass through Great Transformation, "by design or by disaster", therefore ecological economics have to incorporate Postdevelopment theories, Buen vivir and degrowth if they want to really change something.[36]

A 2022 paper by Mark Diesendorf found that limiting global warming to 1,5 degrees with no overshoot would require a reduction of energy consumption. It describes (chapters 4-5) degrowth toward a steady state economy as possible and probably positive. The study ends with the words: "The case for a transition to a steady-state economy with low throughput and low emissions, initially in the high-income economies and then in rapidly growing economies, needs more serious attention and international cooperation.[37]

"Rebound effect" edit

Technologies designed to reduce resource use and improve efficiency are often touted as sustainable or green solutions. Degrowth literature, however, warns about these technological advances due to the "rebound effect", also known as Jevons paradox.[38] This concept is based on observations that when a less resource-exhaustive technology is introduced, behavior surrounding the use of that technology may change, and consumption of that technology could increase or even offset any potential resource savings.[39] In light of the rebound effect, proponents of degrowth hold that the only effective "sustainable" solutions must involve a complete rejection of the growth paradigm and a move to a degrowth paradigm. There are also fundamental limits to technological solutions in the pursuit of degrowth, as all engagements with technology increase the cumulative matter-energy throughput.[40] However, the convergence of digital commons of knowledge and design with distributed manufacturing technologies may arguably hold potential for building degrowth future scenarios.[41]

Mitigation of climate change and determinants of 'growth' edit

 
1.5 °C scenario map under different levels of energy-GDP decoupling, RE speed and NETs[42]

Scientists report that degrowth scenarios, where economic output either "declines" or declines in terms of contemporary economic metrics such as current GDP, have been neglected in considerations of 1.5 °C scenarios reported by the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), finding that investigated degrowth scenarios "minimize many key risks for feasibility and sustainability compared to technology-driven pathways" with a core problem of such being feasibility in the context of contemporary decision-making of politics and globalized rebound- and relocation-effects.[43][42] However, structurally realigning 'economic growth' and socioeconomic activity determination-structures may not be widely debated in both the degrowth community and in degrowth research which may largely focus on reducing economic growth either more generally or without structural alternative but with e.g. nonsystemic political interventions. Similarly, many green growth advocates suggest that contemporary socioeconomic mechanisms and metrics – including for economic growth – can be continued with forms of nonstructural "energy-GDP decoupling".[44][additional citation(s) needed] A study concluded that public services are associated with higher human need satisfaction and lower energy requirements while contemporary forms of economic growth are linked with the opposite, with the contemporary economic system being fundamentally misaligned with the twin goals of meeting human needs and ensuring ecological sustainability, suggesting that prioritizing human well-being and ecological sustainability would be preferable to overgrowth in current metrics of economic growth.[45][46] The word 'degrowth' was mentioned 28 times in the United Nations' IPCC Sixth Assessment Report by Working Group III published in April 2022.[47]

Easterlin Paradox edit

In 1973, Richard Easterlin published a paper entitled "Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence" which finds that after a certain income level or "satiation point", income does not affect happiness levels.[48] The Easterlin Paradox has been reassessed multiple times with varying conclusions.[49][50][51] Furthermore, Easterlin writes consumption levels directly correlate with income level, indicating that after reaching a certain satiation point increased consumption does not affect happiness levels.[48]

Open Localism edit

Open localism is a concept that has been promoted by the degrowth community when envisioning an alternative set of social relations and economic organization. It builds upon the political philosophies of localism and is based on values such as diversity, ecologies of knowledge, and openness. Open localism does not look to create an enclosed community but rather circulate production locally in an open and integrative manner.[52]

Open localism is a direct challenge to the acts of closure regarding identitarian politics[citation needed]. By producing and consuming as much as possible locally, community members enhance their relationships with one another and the surrounding environment.

Degrowth's ideas around open localism share similarities with ideas around the commons while also having clear differences. On the one hand, open localism promotes localized, common production in cooperative-like styles similar to some versions of how commons are organized. On the other hand, open localism does not impose any set of rules or regulations creating a defined boundary, rather it favours a cosmopolitan approach.[53]

Feminism edit

The degrowth movement builds on feminist economics that have criticized measures of economic growth like the GDP as it excludes work mainly done by women such as unpaid care work, that is the work performed to fulfill people's needs, and reproductive work, that is the work sustaining life, first argued by Marilyn Waring.[54] Further, degrowth draws on the critique of socialist feminists like Silvia Federici and Nancy Fraser claiming that capitalist growth builds on the exploitation of women's work.[55][56] Instead of devaluing it, degrowth centers the economy around care,[57] proposing that care work should be organized as a commons.[58]

Centering care goes hand in hand with changing society's time regimes. Degrowth scholars propose a working time reduction.[59] As this does not necessarily lead to gender justice, the redistribution of care work has to be equally pushed.[58] A concrete proposal by Frigga Haug is the 4-in-1-perspective that proposes 4 hours of wage work per day, freeing time for 4 hours of care work, 4 hours of political activities in a direct democracy and 4 hours of personal development through learning.[60]

Furthermore, degrowth draws on materialist ecofeminisms that state the parallel of the exploitation of women and nature in growth-based societies and proposes a subsistence perspective conceptualized by Maria Mies and Ariel Salleh.[61][62] Synergies and opportunities for cross-fertilization between degrowth and feminism were proposed in 2022, through networks including the Feminisms and Degrowth Alliance (FaDA).[58] FaDA argued that the 2023 launch of Degrowth Journal created "a convivial space for generating and exploring knowledge and practice from diverse perspectives".[63]

Decolonialism edit

A relevant concept within the theory of degrowth is decolonialism, which refers to putting an end to the perpetuation of political, social, economic, religious, racial, gender, and epistemological relations of power, domination, and hierarchy of the global north over the global south.[64]

The foundation of this relationship lies in the claim that the imminent socio-ecological collapse is caused by capitalism, which is sustained by economic growth. This economic growth in turn can only be maintained under the eaves of colonialism and extractivism, perpetuating asymmetric power relationships between territories.[65] Colonialism is understood as the appropriation of common goods, resources and labor, which is antagonistic to degrowth principles.

Through colonial domination, capital depresses the prices of inputs and colonial cheapening occurs to the detriment of the oppressed countries[citation needed]. Degrowth criticizes these appropriation mechanisms and enclosure of one territory over another and proposes a provision of human needs through disaccumulation, de-enclosure, and decommodification. It also reconciles with social movements and seeks to recognize the ecological debt to achieve the catch-up, which is postulated as impossible without decolonization.[65][66]

In practice, decolonial practices close to degrowth are observed, such as the movement of Buen vivir or sumak kawsay by various indigenous peoples.

Origins of the movement edit

The contemporary degrowth movement can trace its roots back to the anti-industrialist trends of the 19th century, developed in Great Britain by John Ruskin, William Morris and the Arts and Crafts movement (1819–1900), in the United States by Henry David Thoreau (1817–1862), and in Russia by Leo Tolstoy (1828–1910).[67]

The concept of "degrowth" properly appeared during the 1970s, proposed by André Gorz (1972) and intellectuals such as Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen, Jean Baudrillard, Edward Goldsmith, E.F. Schumacher, Erich Fromm, Paul Goodman and Ivan Illich, whose ideas reflect those of earlier thinkers, such as the economist E. J. Mishan,[68] the industrial historian Tom Rolt,[69] and the radical socialist Tony Turner. The writings of Mahatma Gandhi and J. C. Kumarappa also contain similar philosophies, particularly regarding his support of voluntary simplicity.

More generally, degrowth movements draw on the values of humanism, enlightenment, anthropology and human rights.[70]

Club of Rome reports edit

The world's leaders are correctly fixated on economic growth as the answer to virtually all problems, but they're pushing it with all their might in the wrong direction.

— Donella Meadows, Thinking in Systems[71]

In 1968, the Club of Rome, a think tank headquartered in Winterthur, Switzerland, asked researchers at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology for a report on the limits of our world system and the constraints it puts on human numbers and activity. The report, called The Limits to Growth, published in 1972, became the first significant study to model the consequences of economic growth.[72]

The reports (also known as the Meadows Reports) are not strictly the founding texts of the degrowth movement, as these reports only advise zero growth, and have also been used to support the sustainable development movement. Still, they are considered the first studies explicitly presenting economic growth as a key reason for the increase in global environmental problems such as pollution, shortage of raw materials, and the destruction of ecosystems. The Limits to Growth: The 30-Year Update was published in 2004,[73] and in 2012, a 40-year forecast from Jørgen Randers, one of the book's original authors, was published as 2052: A Global Forecast for the Next Forty Years.[74] In 2021, Club of Rome committee member Gaya Herrington published an article comparing the proposed models' predictions against empirical data trends.[75] The BAU2 ("Business as Usual 2") scenario, predicting "collapse through pollution",[75] as well as the CT ("Comprehensive Technology") scenario, predicting exceptional technological development and gradual decline, were found to align most closely with data observed as of 2019.[75] In September 2022, the Club of Rome released updated predictive models and policy recommendations in a general-audiences book titled Earth for all – A survival guide to humanity.[76]

Lasting influence of Georgescu-Roegen edit

The degrowth movement recognises Romanian American mathematician, statistician and economist Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen as the main intellectual figure inspiring the movement.[77][78]: 548f  [79]: 1742  [80]: xi  [9]: 1f  In his work, The Entropy Law and the Economic Process, Georgescu-Roegen argues that economic scarcity is rooted in physical reality; that all natural resources are irreversibly degraded when put to use in economic activity; that the carrying capacity of Earth—that is, Earth's capacity to sustain human populations and consumption levels—is bound to decrease sometime in the future as Earth's finite stock of mineral resources is presently being extracted and put to use; and consequently, that the world economy as a whole is heading towards an inevitable future collapse.[81]

Georgescu-Roegen's intellectual inspiration to degrowth dates back to the 1970s. When Georgescu-Roegen delivered a lecture at the University of Geneva in 1974, he made a lasting impression on the young, newly graduated French historian and philosopher, Jacques Grinevald [fr], who had earlier been introduced to Georgescu-Roegen's works by an academic advisor. Georgescu-Roegen and Grinevald became friends, and Grinevald devoted his research to a closer study of Georgescu-Roegen's work. As a result, in 1979, Grinevald published a French translation of a selection of Georgescu-Roegen's articles entitled Demain la décroissance: Entropie – Écologie – Économie ('Tomorrow, the Decline: Entropy – Ecology – Economy').[82] Georgescu-Roegen, who spoke French fluently, approved the use of the term décroissance in the title of the French translation. The book gained influence in French intellectual and academic circles from the outset. Later, the book was expanded and republished in 1995 and once again in 2006; however, the word Demain ('tomorrow') was removed from the book's title in the second and third editions.[79]: 1742 [82][83]: 15f 

By the time Grinevald suggested the term décroissance to form part of the title of the French translation of Georgescu-Roegen's work, the term had already permeated French intellectual circles since the early 1970s to signify a deliberate political action to downscale the economy on a permanent and voluntary basis.[21]: 195  Simultaneously, but independently, Georgescu-Roegen criticised the ideas of The Limits to Growth and Herman Daly's steady-state economy in his article, "Energy and Economic Myths", delivered as a series of lectures from 1972, but not published before 1975. In the article, Georgescu-Roegen stated the following:

[Authors who] were set exclusively on proving the impossibility of growth ... were easily deluded by a simple, now widespread, but false syllogism: Since exponential growth in a finite world leads to disasters of all kinds, ecological salvation lies in the stationary state. ... The crucial error consists in not seeing that not only growth, but also a zero-growth state, nay, even a declining state that does not converge toward annihilation, cannot exist forever in a finite environment.[84]: 366f 
... [T]he important, yet unnoticed point [is] that the necessary conclusion of the arguments in favor of that vision [of a stationary state] is that the most desirable state is not a stationary, but a declining one. Undoubtedly, the current growth must cease, nay, be reversed.[84]: 368f  [Emphasis in original]

When reading this particular passage of the text, Grinevald realised that no professional economist of any orientation had ever reasoned like this before. Grinevald also realised the congruence of Georgescu-Roegen's viewpoint and the French debates occurring at the time; this resemblance was captured in the title of the French edition. The translation of Georgescu-Roegen's work into French both fed on and gave further impetus to the concept of décroissance in France—and everywhere else in the francophone world—thereby creating something of an intellectual feedback loop.[79]: 1742  [83]: 15f  [21]: 197f 

By the 2000s, when décroissance was to be translated from French back into English as the catchy banner for the new social movement, the original term "decline" was deemed inappropriate and misdirected for the purpose: "Decline" usually refers to an unexpected, unwelcome, and temporary economic recession, something to be avoided or quickly overcome. Instead, the neologism "degrowth" was coined to signify a deliberate political action to downscale the economy on a permanent, conscious basis—as in the prevailing French usage of the term—something good to be welcomed and maintained, or so followers believe.[78]: 548  [83]: 15f  [85]: 874–876 

When the first international degrowth conference was held in Paris in 2008, the participants honoured Georgescu-Roegen and his work.[86]: 15f, 28, et passim In his manifesto on Petit traité de la décroissance sereine ("Farewell to Growth"), the leading French champion of the degrowth movement, Serge Latouche, credited Georgescu-Roegen as the "main theoretical source of degrowth".[77] Likewise, Italian degrowth theorist Mauro Bonaiuti considered Georgescu-Roegen's work to be "one of the analytical cornerstones of the degrowth perspective".[80]

Schumacher and Buddhist economics edit

E. F. Schumacher's 1973 book Small Is Beautiful predates a unified degrowth movement but nonetheless serves as an important basis for degrowth ideas. In this book he critiques the neo-liberal model of economic development, arguing that an increasing "standard of living", based on consumption is absurd as a goal of economic activity and development. Instead, under what he refers to as Buddhist economics, we should aim to maximize well-being while minimizing consumption.[87]

Ecological and social issues edit

In January 1972, Edward Goldsmith and Robert Prescott-Allen—editors of The Ecologist—published A Blueprint for Survival, which called for a radical programme of decentralisation and deindustrialization to prevent what the authors referred to as "the breakdown of society and the irreversible disruption of the life-support systems on this planet".[88]

In 2019, a summary for policymakers of the largest, most comprehensive study to date of biodiversity and ecosystem services was published by the Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services. The report was finalised in Paris. The main conclusions:

  1. Over the last 50 years, the state of nature has deteriorated at an unprecedented and accelerating rate.
  2. The main drivers of this deterioration have been changes in land and sea use, exploitation of living beings, climate change, pollution and invasive species. These five drivers, in turn, are caused by societal behaviors, from consumption to governance.
  3. Damage to ecosystems undermines 35 of 44 selected UN targets, including the UN General Assembly's Sustainable Development Goals for poverty, hunger, health, water, cities' climate, oceans and land. It can cause problems with food, water and humanity's air supply.
  4. To fix the problem, humanity needs transformative change, including sustainable agriculture, reductions in consumption and waste, fishing quotas and collaborative water management. Page 8 of the report proposes "enabling visions of a good quality of life that do not entail ever-increasing material consumption" as one of the main measures. The report states that "Some pathways chosen to achieve the goals related to energy, economic growth, industry and infrastructure and sustainable consumption and production (Sustainable Development Goals 7, 8, 9 and 12), as well as targets related to poverty, food security and cities (Sustainable Development Goals 1, 2 and 11), could have substantial positive or negative impacts on nature and therefore on the achievement of other Sustainable Development Goals".[89][90]

In a June 2020 paper published in Nature Communications, a group of scientists argue that "green growth" or "sustainable growth" is a myth: "we have to get away from our obsession with economic growth—we really need to start managing our economies in a way that protects our climate and natural resources, even if this means less, no or even negative growth." They conclude that a change in economic paradigms is imperative to prevent environmental destruction, and suggest a range of ideas from the reformist to the radical, with the latter consisting of degrowth, eco-socialism and eco-anarchism.[91][92]

In June 2020, the official site of one of the organizations promoting degrowth published an article by Vijay Kolinjivadi, an expert in political ecology, arguing that the emergence of COVID-19 is linked to the ecological crisis.[93]

The 2019 World Scientists' Warning of a Climate Emergency and its 2021 update have asserted that economic growth is a primary driver of the overexploitation of ecosystems, and to preserve the biosphere and mitigate climate change civilization must, in addition to other fundamental changes including stabilizing population growth and adopting largely plant-based diets, "shift from GDP growth and the pursuit of affluence toward sustaining ecosystems and improving human well-being by prioritizing basic needs and reducing inequality."[94][95] In an opinion piece published in Al Jazeera, Jason Hickel states that this paper, which was has more than 11,000 scientist cosigners, demonstrates that there is a "strong scientific consensus" towards abandoning "GDP as a measure of progress."[96]

In a 2022 comment published in Nature, Hickel, Giorgos Kallis, Juliet Schor, Julia Steinberger and others say that both the IPCC and the IPBES "suggest that degrowth policies should be considered in the fight against climate breakdown and biodiversity loss, respectively".[6]

Degrowth movement edit

Conferences edit

The movement has included international conferences [97] promoted by the network Research & Degrowth (R&D).[98] The First International Conference on Economic Degrowth for Ecological Sustainability and Social Equity in Paris (2008) was a discussion about the financial, social, cultural, demographic, and environmental crisis caused by the deficiencies of capitalism and an explanation of the main principles of degrowth.[99][100] Further conferences were in Barcelona (2010),[101] Montreal (2012),[102] Venice (2012),[103] Leipzig (2014), Budapest (2016),[104] Malmö (2018),[105], and Zagreb (2023).[106]

Barcelona Conference (2010) edit

The Second International Conference in Barcelona focused on specific ways to implement a degrowth society.

Concrete proposals have been developed for future political actions, including:

The Barcelona conference had little influence on the world economic and political order. Criticism of the proposals arrived at in Barcelona, mostly financial, have inhibited change.[110]

Post Growth Conference (2018) edit

The Post-Growth 2018 Conference was a two-day event held on the 18th of September at the European Parliament in Brussels to discuss a vision of the European Union beyond traditional development metrics centered around GDP. It built on thematic workshops organized by multiple stakeholders. The workshops encouraged building a dialogue between actors and seeking for applicable policy alternatives.[111][112]

The conference was paired with a petition signed by 238 academics to call on the EU to plan for a post-growth that prioritized human and ecological wellbeing over GDP.[112]

Degrowth around the world edit

Although not explicitly called degrowth, movements inspired by similar concepts and terminologies can be found around the world, including Buen Vivir[113] in Latin America, the Zapatistas in Mexico, the Kurdish Rojava or Eco-Swaraj in India, and the sufficiency economy in Thailand.[114]

The Cuban economic situation has been of interest to some degrowth advocates because its limits on growth were socially imposed (although as a result of geopolitics).[115]: 7  Although the Special Period following the disintegration of the Soviet Union resulted in severe impairment of the Cuban health system, certain positive health changes also resulted as the forced changes to travel and food consumption patterns resulted in increased levels of physical activity and decreased obesity levels.[115]: 71 

Relation to other social movements edit

The degrowth movement has a variety of relations to other social movements and alternative economic visions, which range from collaboration to partial overlap. The Konzeptwerk Neue Ökonomie (Laboratory for New Economic Ideas), which hosted the 2014 international Degrowth conference in Leipzig, has published a project entitled "Degrowth in movement(s)"[116] in 2017, which maps relationships with 32 other social movements and initiatives. The relation to the environmental justice movement is especially visible.[9]

Another set of movements the degrowth movement finds synergy with is the wave of initiatives and networks inspired by the commons.[15] Some main commons networks include: School of Commoning in Barcelona, Commoning Europe, and the Commons-Institute in Germany. The main overlap stems from a high level of self organization to sustainably share resources through a different logic outside of capitalist organization. This is directly countering the hyper privatization currently embedded in contemporary capitalism, which both movements are attempting to counter in some way.[117] For example, initiatives inspired by commons could be food cooperatives, open-source platforms, and group management of resources such as energy or water. These decentralized, direct democratic forms of self-management relate to the degrowth movement regarding inclusive political representation, where the people are actively involved in producing and distributing shared resources.[118][119] In short, the movements have shared values of inclusion, sustainable use of resources, self-organization, conviviality, shared knowledge production and emphasize use value over exchange value. Degrowth also finds synergy with technology-oriented movements such as Cosmopolitan localism or cosmolocalism. Cosmolocalism has been proposed as a structural framework for degrowth technology, as it organises production by prioritising socio-ecological well-being over corporate profits, over-production and excess consumption.[120]

Economic anthropologist Jason Hickel, a proponent of degrowth, sees an opportunity for the degrowth movement to be enhanced by modern monetary theory (MMT), in which the power of "the government's role as the issuer of currency" can be harnessed to bring the economy back into balance with the living world while simultaneously reducing inequality by providing high quality universal public services (in healthcare, education, affordable housing, and transportation), implementing the rapid development of renewable energy infrastructure to completely phase out fossil fuels in a shorter period of time, and establishing a public job guarantee for 30 hours a week at a living wage doing decommodified, socially useful work in the public services sector, and also useful work in renewable energy development and ecosystem restoration. Hickel notes that providing a living wage at 30 hours a week also has the added benefit of shifting income from capital to labor. And he suggests that taxation can be used to "reduce demand in order to bring resource and energy use down to target levels," and specifically to reduce the purchasing power of the affluent. He concludes:

MMT proposals align elegantly with one of degrowth's key observations, namely, that if growthism depends on the perpetual creation of artificial scarcity, then by reversing artificial scarcity – by providing public abundance – we can dismantle the growth imperative. As Giorgos Kallis has put it, "capitalism cannot survive under conditions of abundance". MMT provides an opportunity for us to create a post-growth, post-capitalist economy.[121]

Criticisms, challenges and dilemmas edit

Critiques of degrowth concern the negative connotation that the term "degrowth" imparts, the misapprehension that growth is seen as unambiguously bad, the challenges and feasibility of a degrowth transition, as well as the entanglement of desirable aspects of modernity with the growth paradigm.

Criticisms edit

Negative connotation edit

The use of the term "degrowth" is criticized for being detrimental to the degrowth movement because it could carry a negative connotation,[122] in opposition to the positively perceived "growth".[123] "Growth" is associated with the "up" direction and positive experiences, while "down" generates the opposite associations.[124] Research in political psychology has shown that the initial negative association of a concept, such as of "degrowth" with the negatively perceived "down", can bias how the subsequent information on that concept is integrated at the unconscious level.[125] At the conscious level, degrowth can be interpreted negatively as the contraction of the economy,[122][126] although this is not the goal of a degrowth transition, but rather one of its expected consequences.[2] In the current economic system, a contraction of the economy is associated with a recession and its ensuing austerity measures, job cuts, or lower salaries.[126] Noam Chomsky commented on the use of the term: "When you say 'degrowth' it frightens people. It's like saying you're going to have to be poorer tomorrow than you are today, and it doesn't mean that."[127]

Since "degrowth" contains the term "growth", there is also a risk of the term having a backfire effect, which would reinforce the initial positive attitude toward growth.[122] "Degrowth" is also criticized for being a confusing term, since its aim is not to halt economic growth as the word implies. Instead, "a-growth" is proposed as an alternative concept that emphasizes that growth ceases to be an important policy objective, but that it can still be achieved as a side-effect of environmental and social policies.[126][128]

Marxist critique edit

Traditional Marxists distinguish between two types of value creation: that which is useful to mankind, and that which only serves the purpose of accumulating capital.[9]: 86–87  Traditional Marxists consider that it is the exploitative nature and control of the capitalist production relations that is the determinant and not the quantity. According to Jean Zin, while the justification for degrowth is valid, it is not a solution to the problem.[129] Other Marxist writers have adopted positions close to the de-growth perspective. For example, John Bellamy Foster[130] and Fred Magdoff,[131] in common with David Harvey, Immanuel Wallerstein, Paul Sweezy and others focus on endless capital accumulation as the basic principle and goal of capitalism. This is the source of economic growth and, in the view of these writers, results in an unsustainable growth imperative. Foster and Magdoff develop Marx's own concept of the metabolic rift, something he noted in the exhaustion of soils by capitalist systems of food production, though this is not unique to capitalist systems of food production as seen in the Aral Sea. Many degrowth theories and ideas are based on neo-Marxist theory.[9] Foster emphasizes that degrowth "is not aimed at austerity, but at finding a 'prosperous way down' from our current extractivist, wasteful, ecologically unsustainable, maldeveloped, exploitative, and unequal, class-hierarchical world."[132]

Systems theoretical critique edit

In stressing the negative rather than the positive side(s) of growth, the majority of degrowth proponents remain focused on (de-)growth, thus giving continued attention to the issue of growth, leading to continued attention to the arguments that sustainable growth is possible. One way to avoid giving attention to growth might be extending from the economic concept of growth, which proponents of both growth and degrowth commonly adopt, to a broader concept of growth that allows for the observation of growth in other sociological characteristics of society. A corresponding "recoding" of "growth-obsessed", capitalist organizations was proposed by Steffen Roth.[133]

Challenges edit

Lack of macroeconomics for sustainability edit

It is reasonable for society to worry about recession as economic growth has been the unanimous goal around the globe in the past decades. However, in some advanced countries, there are attempts to develop a model for a regrowth economy. For instance, the Cool Japan strategy has proven to be instructive for Japan, which has been a static economy for almost decades.[134]

Political and social spheres edit

According to some scholars in Sociology, the growth imperative is deeply entrenched in market capitalist societies such that it is necessary for their stability.[135] Moreover, the institutions of modern societies, such as the nation state, welfare, labor market, education, academia, law and finance, have co-evolved with growth to sustain them.[136] A degrowth transition thus requires not only a change of the economic system but of all the systems on which it relies. As most people in modern societies are dependent on those growth-oriented institutions, the challenge of a degrowth transition also lies in individual resistance to move away from growth.[137]

Land privatisation edit

Baumann, Alexander and Burdon [138] suggest that "the Degrowth movement needs to give more attention to land and housing costs, which are significant barriers hindering true political and economic agency and any grassroots driven degrowth transition." They are saying that land (something we all need like air and water) privatisation creates an absolute economic growth determinant. They point out that even one who is fully committed to degrowth nevertheless has no option but decades of market growth participation to pay rent or mortgage. Because of this, land privatisation is a structural impediment to moving forward that makes degrowth economically and politically unviable. They conclude that without addressing land privatisation (the market's inaugural privatisation - primitive accumulation) the degrowth movement's strategies cannot succeed. Just as land enclosure (privatisation) initiated capitalism (economic growth), degrowth must start with reclaiming land commons.[139]

Agriculture edit

When it comes to agriculture, a degrowth society would require a shift from industrial agriculture to less intensive and more sustainable agricultural practices such as permaculture or organic agriculture. Still, it is not clear if any of those alternatives could feed the current and projected global population.[140][141] In the case of organic agriculture, Germany, for example, would not be able to feed its population under ideal organic yields over all of its arable land without meaningful changes to patterns of consumption, such as reducing meat consumption and food waste.[142][140] Moreover, labour productivity of non-industrial agriculture is significantly lower due to the reduced use or absence of fossil fuels, which leaves much less labour for other sectors.[143] Potential solutions to this challenge include scaling up approaches such as community-supported agriculture (CSA).

Dilemmas edit

Given that modernity has emerged with high levels of energy and material throughput, there is an apparent compromise between desirable aspects of modernity[144] (e.g., social justice, gender equality, long life expectancy, low infant mortality) and unsustainable levels of energy and material use.[145] Some researchers, however, argue that the decline in income inequality and rise in social mobility occurring under capitalism from the late 1940s to the 1960s was a product of the heavy bargaining power of labor unions and increased wealth and income redistribution during that time; while also pointing to the rise in income inequality in the 1970s following the collapse of labor unions and weakening of state welfare measures.[146] Others also argue that modern capitalism maintains gender inequalities by means of advertising, messaging in consumer goods, and social media.[147]

Another way of looking at the argument that the development of desirable aspects of modernity require unsustainable energy and material use is through the lens of the Marxist tradition, which relates the superstructure (culture, ideology, institutions) and the base (material conditions of life, division of labor). A degrowth society, with its drastically different material conditions, could produce equally drastic changes in society's cultural and ideological spheres.[145] The political economy of global capitalism has generated a lot of social and environmental bads, such as socioeconomic inequality and ecological devastation, which in turn have also generated a lot of goods through individualization and increased spatial and social mobility.[148] At the same time, some argue the widespread individualization promulgated by a capitalist political economy is a bad due to its undermining of solidarity, aligned with democracy as well as collective, secondary, and primary forms of caring,[149] and simultaneous encouragement of mistrust of others, highly competitive interpersonal relationships, blame of failure on individual shortcomings, prioritization of one's self-interest, and peripheralization of the conceptualization of human work required to create and sustain people.[150] In this view, the widespread individuation resulting from capitalism may impede degrowth measures, requiring a change in actions to benefit society rather than the individual self.

Some argue the political economy of capitalism has allowed social emancipation at the level of gender equality,[151] disability, sexuality and anti-racism that has no historical precedent. However, others dispute social emancipation as being a direct product of capitalism or question the emancipation that has resulted. The feminist writer Nancy Holmstrom, for example, argues that capitalism's negative impacts on women outweigh the positive impacts, and women tend to be hurt by the system. In her examination of China following the Chinese Communist Revolution, Holmstrom notes that women were granted state-assisted freedoms to equal education, childcare, healthcare, abortion, marriage, and other social supports.[152] Thus, whether the social emancipation achieved in Western society under capitalism may coexist with degrowth is ambiguous.

Doyal and Gough allege that the modern capitalist system is built on the exploitation of female reproductive labor as well as that of the Global South, and sexism and racism are embedded in its structure. Therefore, some theories (such as Eco-Feminism or political ecology) argue that there cannot be equality regarding gender and the hierarchy between the Global North and South within capitalism.[153]

The structural properties of growth present another barrier to degrowth as growth shapes and is enforced by institutions, norms, culture, technology, identities, etc. The social ingraining of growth manifests in peoples' aspirations, thinking, bodies, mindsets, and relationships. Together, growth's role in social practices and in socio-economic institutions present unique challenges to the success of the degrowth movement.[154] Another potential barrier to degrowth is the need for a rapid transition to a degrowth society due to climate change and the potential negative impacts of a rapid social transition including disorientation, conflict, and decreased well-being.[154]

In the United States, a large barrier to the support of the degrowth movement is the modern education system, including both primary and higher learning institutions. Beginning in the second term of the Reagan administration, the education system in the US was restructured to enforce neoliberal ideology by means of privatization schemes such as commercialization and performance contracting, implementation of standards and accountability measures incentivizing schools to adopt a uniform curriculum, and higher education accreditation and curricula designed to affirm market values and current power structures and avoid critical thought concerning the relations between those in power, ethics, authority, history, and knowledge.[155] The degrowth movement, based on the empirical assumption that resources are finite and growth is limited,[156] clashes with the limitless growth ideology associated with neoliberalism and the market values affirmed in schools, and therefore faces a major social barrier in gaining widespread support in the US.[citation needed]

Nevertheless, co-evolving aspects of global capitalism, liberal modernity, and the market society, are closely tied and will be difficult to separate to maintain liberal and cosmopolitan values in a degrowth society.[148] At the same time, the goal of the degrowth movement is progression rather than regression, and researchers point out that neoclassical economic models indicate neither negative nor zero growth would harm economic stability or full employment.[156] Several assert the main barriers to the movement are social and structural factors clashing with implementing degrowth measures.[156][154][157]

Healthcare edit

It has been pointed out that there is an apparent trade-off between the ability of modern healthcare systems to treat individual bodies to their last breath and the broader global ecological risk of such an energy and resource intensive care. If this trade-off exists, a degrowth society must choose between prioritizing the ecological integrity and the ensuing collective health or maximizing the healthcare provided to individuals.[158] However, many degrowth scholars argue that the current system produces both psychological and physical damage to people. They insist that societal prosperity should be measured by well-being, not GDP.[9]: 142 

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ Trainer, Ted (2012). "De-growth: Do you realise what it means?". Futures. 44 (6): 590–599. doi:10.1016/j.futures.2012.03.020.
  2. ^ a b Kallis, Giorgos; Kostakis, Vasilis; Lange, Steffen; et al. (2018). "Research On Degrowth". Annual Review of Environment and Resources. 43 (1): 291–316. doi:10.1146/annurev-environ-102017-025941. ISSN 1543-5938.
  3. ^ Hickel, Jason (2021). "What does degrowth mean? A few points of clarification". Globalizations. 18 (7): 1105–1111. doi:10.1080/14747731.2020.1812222. S2CID 221800076.
  4. ^ Buch-Hansen, Hubert; Nesterova, Iana (2023). "Less and more: Conceptualising degrowth transformations". Ecological Economics. 205: 107731. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2022.107731.
  5. ^ Akbulut, Bengi (2021). "Degrowth". Rethinking Marxism. 33 (1): 98–110. doi:10.1080/08935696.2020.1847014. S2CID 232116190.
  6. ^ a b Hickel, Jason; Kallis, Giorgos; Jackson, Tim; O'Neill, Daniel W.; Schor, Juliet B.; Steinberger, Julia K.; et al. (December 12, 2022). "Degrowth can work — here's how science can help". Nature. 612 (7940): 400–403. Bibcode:2022Natur.612..400H. doi:10.1038/d41586-022-04412-x. PMID 36510013. S2CID 254614532.
  7. ^ Pettinger, Tejvan (27 April 2020). "Degrowth - definition, examples and criticisms". Economics Help.
  8. ^ Kongshøj, Kristian (2023). "Social policy in a future of degrowth? Challenges for decommodification, commoning and public support". Humanities and Social Sciences Communications. 10 (1): 1–11. doi:10.1057/s41599-023-02255-z.
  9. ^ a b c d e f D'Alisa, Giacomo; et al., eds. (2015). Degrowth: A Vocabulary for a New Era (Book info page containing download samples). London: Routledge. ISBN 9781138000766.
  10. ^ Hickel, Jason; Kallis, Giorgos; Jackson, Tim; O’Neill, Daniel W.; Schor, Juliet B.; Steinberger, Julia K.; Victor, Peter A.; Ürge-Vorsatz, Diana (December 2022). "Degrowth can work — here's how science can help". Nature. 612 (7940): 400–403. Bibcode:2022Natur.612..400H. doi:10.1038/d41586-022-04412-x. PMID 36510013. S2CID 254614532.
  11. ^ "Degrowth - an overview | ScienceDirect Topics". www.sciencedirect.com. Retrieved 2023-09-11.
  12. ^ "Degrowth: what's behind this economic theory and why it matters today". World Economic Forum. 2022-06-15. Retrieved 2023-09-11.
  13. ^ Horowitz, Julia (2022-11-13). "Degrowth: A dangerous idea or the answer to the world's biggest crisis? | CNN Business". CNN. Retrieved 2023-09-11.
  14. ^ Bokat-Lindell, Spencer (2021-09-16). "Opinion | Do We Need to Shrink the Economy to Stop Climate Change?". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 2023-09-11.
  15. ^ a b Nelson, Anitra (2024-01-31). "Degrowth as a Concept and Practice: Introduction". The Commons Social Change Library. Retrieved 2024-02-20.
  16. ^ Hickel, Jason (2022). Less is more (1 ed.). London: Penguin Books. pp. 170–179. ISBN 9781786091215.
  17. ^ Akbulut, Bengi (2021). "Degrowth, Rethinking Marxism". Rethinking Marxism. 33 (1): 98–110. doi:10.1080/08935696.2020.1847014. S2CID 232116190. Retrieved 28 April 2023.
  18. ^ Demaria, Federico; Schneider, François; Sekulova, Filka; Martinez-Alier, Joan (2013). "What is Degrowth? From an Activist Slogan to a Social Movement". Environmental Values. 22 (2): 191–215. doi:10.3197/096327113X13581561725194. ISSN 0963-2719. JSTOR 23460978. S2CID 55888884.
  19. ^ Demaria, Federico; Kothari, Ashish; Salleh, Ariel; Escobar, Arturo; Acosta, Alberto (2019). Pluriverse. A Post-Development Dictionary. New Delhi: Tulika Books. ISBN 9788193732984.
  20. ^ "What is degrowth?". degrowth.info. Archived from the original on 30 January 2021. Retrieved 29 April 2020.
  21. ^ a b c d e Demaria, Federico; et al. (2013). "What is Degrowth? From an Activist Slogan to a Social Movement" (PDF). Environmental Values. 22 (2): 191–215. doi:10.3197/096327113X13581561725194. S2CID 55888884. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2016-05-27.
  22. ^ Cosme, Inês; Santos, Rui; O'Neill, Daniel W. (2017-04-15). "Assessing the degrowth discourse: A review and analysis of academic degrowth policy proposals". Journal of Cleaner Production. 149: 321–334. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.02.016. ISSN 0959-6526.
  23. ^ Cosme, Inês; Parrique, Timothée; Fitzpatrickl, Nick (2022). "Exploring degrowth policy proposals: A systematic mapping with thematic synthesis". Journal of Cleaner Production. 365: 132764. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2022.132764. hdl:10362/150706. S2CID 249875134.
  24. ^ Kallis, Giorgos (2023-04-01). "Degrowth and the Barcelona School, open access". The Barcelona School of Ecological Economics and Political Ecology. Studies in Ecological Economics. 8: 83–90. doi:10.1007/978-3-031-22566-6. ISBN 978-3-031-22565-9. S2CID 257222514.
  25. ^ Haberl, Helmut; Wiedenhofer, Dominik; Virág, Doris; Kalt, Gerald; Plank, Barbara; Brockway, Paul; Fishman, Tomer; Hausknost, Daniel; Krausmann, Fridolin; Leon-Gruchalski, Bartholomäus; Mayer, Andreas (2020-06-10). "A systematic review of the evidence on decoupling of GDP, resource use and GHG emissions, part II: synthesizing the insights". Environmental Research Letters. 15 (6): 065003. Bibcode:2020ERL....15f5003H. doi:10.1088/1748-9326/ab842a. ISSN 1748-9326. S2CID 216453887.
  26. ^ a b Antal, Miklós; Van Den Bergh, Jeroen C.J.M. (2016-02-17). "Green growth and climate change: conceptual and empirical considerations". Climate Policy. 16 (2): 165–177. Bibcode:2016CliPo..16..165A. doi:10.1080/14693062.2014.992003. ISSN 1469-3062. S2CID 153816870.
  27. ^ a b c "Decoupling debunked – Evidence and arguments against green growth as a sole strategy for sustainability". EEB - The European Environmental Bureau. Retrieved 2022-05-31.
  28. ^ Hickel, Jason; Kallis, Giorgos (2020-06-06). "Is Green Growth Possible?". New Political Economy. 25 (4): 469–486. doi:10.1080/13563467.2019.1598964. ISSN 1356-3467. S2CID 159148524.
  29. ^ Bardi, U. (2008) 'Peak Caviar'. The Oil Drum: Europe. http://europe.theoildrum.com/node/4367
  30. ^ "Peak Oil Reports". Resilience.org. October 20, 2009.
  31. ^ Corvellec, Hervé; Paulsson, Alexander (2023-03-01). "Resource shifting: Resourcification and de-resourcification for degrowth". Ecological Economics. 205: 107703. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2022.107703. ISSN 0921-8009. S2CID 254388285.
  32. ^ "Data Sources". footprintnetwork.org. Archived from the original on 2009-10-01.
  33. ^ Merz, Joseph J; Barnard, Phoebe; Rees, William E; Smith, Dane; Maroni, Mat; Rhodes, Christopher J; Dederer, Julia H; Bajaj, Nandita; Joy, Michael K; Wiedmann, Thomas; Sutherland, Rory (July 2023). "World scientists' warning: The behavioural crisis driving ecological overshoot". Science Progress. 106 (3). doi:10.1177/00368504231201372. ISSN 0036-8504. PMC 10515534. PMID 37728669.
  34. ^ Lorek, Sylvia; Fuchs, Doris (2013). "Strong sustainable consumption governance – precondition for a degrowth path?" (PDF). Journal of Cleaner Production. 38: 36–43. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2011.08.008. S2CID 49362153.
  35. ^ a b Latouche, S. (2004). Degrowth Economics: Why less should be so much more. Le Monde Diplomatique.
  36. ^ Beling, Adrián E.; Vanhulst, Julien; Demaria, Federico; Rabi, Violeta; Carballo, Ana E.; Pelenc, Jérôme (11 September 2017). "Discursive Synergies for a 'Great Transformation' Towards Sustainability: Pragmatic Contributions to a Necessary Dialogue Between Human Development, Degrowth, and Buen Vivir". Ecological Economics. 144: 304–313. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2017.08.025. Retrieved 21 July 2020.
  37. ^ Diesendorf, Mark (22 April 2022). "Scenarios for mitigating CO2 emissions from energy supply in the absence of CO2 removal". Climate Policy. 22 (7): 882–896. Bibcode:2022CliPo..22..882D. doi:10.1080/14693062.2022.2061407. S2CID 248358617. Retrieved 1 June 2022.
  38. ^ (Zehner 2012), pp.172–73, 333–34
  39. ^ Binswanger, M. (2001). "Technological Progress and Sustainable Development: What About the Rebound Effect?". Ecological Economics. 36 (1): 119–32. doi:10.1016/S0921-8009(00)00214-7.
  40. ^ Heikkurinen, Pasi (2018). "Degrowth by means of technology? A treatise for an ethos of releasement" (PDF). Journal of Cleaner Production. 197: 1654–1665. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.07.070. S2CID 55830276.
  41. ^ Kostakis, Vasilis; Latoufis, Kostas; Liarokapis, Minas; Bauwens, Michel (2018). "The convergence of digital commons with local manufacturing from a degrowth perspective: Two illustrative cases" (PDF). Journal of Cleaner Production. 197: 1684–1693. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.09.077. S2CID 43975556. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2019-06-09.
  42. ^ a b Keyßer, Lorenz T.; Lenzen, Manfred (2021-05-11). "1.5 °C degrowth scenarios suggest the need for new mitigation pathways". Nature Communications. 12 (1): 2676. Bibcode:2021NatCo..12.2676K. doi:10.1038/s41467-021-22884-9. ISSN 2041-1723. PMC 8113441. PMID 33976156.   Available under CC BY 4.0.
  43. ^ "1.5°C degrowth scenarios suggest need for new mitigation pathways". phys.org. Retrieved 14 June 2021.Alternative Link
  44. ^ "Green growth vs degrowth: are we missing the point?". Resilience. 2020-12-07. Retrieved 23 June 2021.
  45. ^ "Securing decent living standards for all while reducing global energy use". phys.org. Retrieved 10 July 2021.
  46. ^ Vogel, Jefim; Steinberger, Julia K.; O'Neill, Daniel W.; Lamb, William F.; Krishnakumar, Jaya (29 June 2021). "Socio-economic conditions for satisfying human needs at low energy use: An international analysis of social provisioning". Global Environmental Change. 69: 102287. doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2021.102287. ISSN 0959-3780.
  47. ^ How the corporate interests and political elites watered down the world's most important climate report MR Online. 2022.
  48. ^ a b Easterlin, Richard A. "Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence." Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of Moses Abramovitz, Elsevier Inc, 1974, pp. 89–125. Web.
  49. ^ Stevenson, Betsey, and Justin Wolfers. "Economic Growth and Subjective Well-Being: Reassessing the Easterlin Paradox." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 2008, no. 1, Brookings Institution, 2008, pp. 1–87. Web.
  50. ^ Frank, Robert H. "The Easterlin Paradox Revisited." Emotion (Washington, D.C.), vol. 12, no. 6, American Psychological Association, 2012, pp. 1188–91. Web.
  51. ^ Mentus, Vladimir, and Marko Vladisavljevic. "Easterlin Paradox Revisited: Do Increases in Income Bring Higher Levels of Income Satisfaction?" Sociologija, vol. 63, no. 2, 2021, pp. 220–35. Web.
  52. ^ Schneider, Francois; Sekulova, Filka. open localism (PDF). Leipzig.
  53. ^ Schneider, François, and Anitra Nelson. "'Open localism'–on Xue and Vansintjan III." Housing for Degrowth. Routledge, 2018. 223-230.
  54. ^ Waring, Marilyn (1989). If Women Counted: A New Feminist Economics. London: Macmillan. ISBN 0-333-49262-5.
  55. ^ Federici, Silvia (17 June 2020). "Feminism and the Politics of the Commons". Retrieved 4 April 2022.
  56. ^ Fraser, Nancy (2017). Crisis of Care? On the Social-Reproductive Contradictions of Contemporary Capitalism. In: Bhattacharya, Tithi. Social Reproduction Theory: Remapping Class, Recentering Oppression. London: Pluto Press. pp. 21–36.
  57. ^ Kallis, Giorgos; Demaria, Federico; D'Alisa, Giacomo (2015). Introduction: Degrowth. In: Kallis, Giorgos; Demaria, Federico; D'Alisa, Giacomo. Degrowth: Vocabulary for a New Era. New York: Routledge. pp. 1–17.
  58. ^ a b c Dengler, Corinna; Lang, Miriam (2022). "Commoning Care: Feminist Degrowth Visions for a Socio-Ecological Transformation". Feminist Economics. 28 (1): 1–28. doi:10.1080/13545701.2021.1942511. S2CID 240534324.
  59. ^ Kallis, Giorgos (2018). Degrowth. Agenda Publishing. ISBN 978-1-911116-79-0.
  60. ^ Haug, Frigga (2009). Die Vier-in-einem-Perspektive. Politik von Frauen für eine neue Linke. Hamburg: Argument Verlag. ISBN 978-978-3-88619-3.
  61. ^ Mies, Maria; Bennholdt-Thomsen, Veronika (1999). The Subsistence Perspective: Beyond the Globalised Economy. Zed Books.
  62. ^ Salleh, Ariel (1997). Ecofeminism as Politics; Nature, Marx and the Postmodern. When Feminism Fails. pp. 153–174. doi:10.1080/08854300.2018.1509619. S2CID 149712144.
  63. ^ Sourayan Mookerjea; Susan Paulson; Corinna Dengler; Nadine Gerner; Taís Sonetti–González; Lina Hansen; Anna Saave (3 May 2023). "Why are feminist perspectives, analyses, and actions vital to degrowth?". Degrowth Journal. 1: 00046. Wikidata Q118151474. Archived from the original on 4 May 2023.
  64. ^ Gómez, Martha; Saldarriaga, Dora; López, Maria; Zapata, Lina (2017). Decolonial and Postcolonial Studies. Theories about Modernity, Coloniality, and Eurocentrism.
  65. ^ a b Hickel, Jason (2021). "The anti-colonial politics of degrowth" (PDF). Political Geography. 88: 102404. doi:10.1016/j.polgeo.2021.102404. S2CID 235549247.
  66. ^ Wuttke, Tobias (2021). Reconciling catch-up industrialisation with de-growth.
  67. ^ "Degrowth: A Vocabulary for a New Era (Paperback) - Routledge". Routledge.com. p. 134. Retrieved 2016-02-28.
  68. ^ Mishan, Ezra J., The Costs of Economic Growth, Staples Press, 1967.
  69. ^ Rolt, L. T. C. (1947). High Horse Riderless. George Allen & Unwin. p. 171.
  70. ^ d'Alisa, Giacomo; Demaria, Federico; Cattaneo, Claudio (2013). "Civil and Uncivil Actors for a Degrowth Society" (PDF). Journal of Civil Society. 9 (2): 212–224. doi:10.1080/17448689.2013.788935. S2CID 55508495.
  71. ^ Donella Meadows, edited by Diana Wright, Thinking in Systems: A Primer, Chelsea Green Publishing, 2008, page 146 (ISBN 9781603580557).
  72. ^ "The Limits to Growth+50". Club of Rome. Retrieved 7 November 2023.
  73. ^ Meadows, Donella H.; Randers, Jorgen; Meadows, Dennis L. (2004). The Limits to Growth: The 30-Year Update. White River Junction VT: Chelsea Green Publishing Co. ISBN 1931498512. Retrieved 27 November 2017.
  74. ^ Randers, Jørgen (2012). 2052: A Global Forecast for the Next Forty Years. White River Junction VT: Chelsea Green Publishing Co. ISBN 978-1-60358-467-8. Retrieved 29 March 2019.
  75. ^ a b c Herrington, Gaya (June 2021). "Update to limits to growth: Comparing the World3 model with empirical data". Journal of Industrial Ecology. 25 (3): 614–626. doi:10.1111/jiec.13084. ISSN 1088-1980. S2CID 226019712.
  76. ^ Dixson-Declève, Sandrine (2022). Earth for all: a survival guide for humanity: a report to the Club of Rome (2022), fifty years after The limits of growth (1972). Owen Gaffney, Jayati Ghosh, Jørgen Randers, Johan Rockström, Per Espen Stoknes, Club of Rome. Gabriola Island, British Columbia, Canada: New Society Publishers. ISBN 978-0-86571-986-6. OCLC 1315537859.
  77. ^ a b (Latouche 2009), pp. 13-16
  78. ^ a b Kerschner, Christian (2010). "Economic de-growth vs. steady-state economy" (PDF). Journal of Cleaner Production. 18 (6): 544–551. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2009.10.019.
  79. ^ a b c Martínez-Alier, Juan; et al. (2010). "Sustainable de-growth: Mapping the context, criticisms and future prospects of an emergent paradigm" (PDF). Ecological Economics. 69 (9): 1741–1747. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2010.04.017.
  80. ^ a b Bonaiuti, Mauro, ed. (2011). From Bioeconomics to Degrowth: Georgescu-Roegen's "New Economics" in eight essays (Book info page at publisher's site). London: Routledge. ISBN 9780415587006.
  81. ^ Georgescu-Roegen, Nicholas (1971). The Entropy Law and the Economic Process (Full book accessible at Scribd). Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0674257801.
  82. ^ a b Georgescu-Roegen, Nicholas (1995) [1979]. Grinevald, Jacques [in French]; Rens, Ivo [in French] (eds.). La Décroissance: Entropie – Écologie – Économie (PDF contains full book) (2nd ed.). Paris: Sang de la terre.
  83. ^ a b c Grinevald, Jacques [in French] (2008). "Introduction to Georgescu-Roegen and Degrowth" (PDF contains all conference proceedings). In Flipo, Fabrice; Schneider, François [in French] (eds.). Proceedings of the First International Conference on Economic De-Growth for Ecological Sustainability and Social Equity. Paris: European Society of Ecological Economics. pp. 14–17.
  84. ^ a b Georgescu-Roegen, Nicholas (1975). "Energy and Economic Myths" (PDF). Southern Economic Journal. 41 (3): 347–381. doi:10.2307/1056148. JSTOR 1056148.
  85. ^ Kallis, Giorgos (2011). "In defense of degrowth" (PDF). Ecological Economics. 70 (5): 873–880. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2010.12.007.; Kallis, Giorgos (February 2015). "The Degrowth Alternative". Great Transition Initiative.
  86. ^ Flipo, Fabrice; Schneider, François [in French], eds. (2008). Proceedings of the First International Conference on Economic De-Growth for Ecological Sustainability and Social Equity (PDF contains all conference proceedings). Paris: European Society of Ecological Economics.
  87. ^ Schumacher, E. F. (1973). Small is Beautiful: Economics as if People Mattered. New York: Perennial Library.
  88. ^ "A Blueprint for Survival, The Ecologist Vol. 2, No. 1. Preface". Archived from the original on 2009-09-07. Retrieved 2008-04-10.
  89. ^ Summary for policymakers of the global assessment report on biodiversity and ecosystem services of the Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services (PDF). the Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services. 6 May 2019. Retrieved 10 May 2019.
  90. ^ "Why Biodiversity Loss Hurts Humans as Much as Climate Change Does". Deutsche Welle. May 6, 2019. Retrieved 10 May 2019.
  91. ^ "Overconsumption and growth economy key drivers of environmental crises" (Press release). Phys.org. University of New South Wales. Retrieved 22 June 2020.
  92. ^ Wiedmann, Thomas; Lenzen, Manfred; Keyßer, Lorenz T.; Steinberger, Julia K. (2020). "Scientists' warning on affluence". Nature Communications. 11 (3107): 3107. Bibcode:2020NatCo..11.3107W. doi:10.1038/s41467-020-16941-y. PMC 7305220. PMID 32561753.
  93. ^ Kolinjivadi, Vijay (2 April 2020). "This pandemic IS ecological breakdown: different tempo, same song". Uneven Earth. Retrieved 20 July 2020.
  94. ^ Ripple, William J.; et al. (November 5, 2019), "World Scientists' Warning of a Climate Emergency", BioScience, 70: 8–12, doi:10.1093/biosci/biz088, hdl:1808/30278, retrieved February 21, 2022
  95. ^ Ripple, William J.; et al. (July 28, 2021), "World Scientists' Warning of a Climate Emergency 2021", BioScience, 71 (9): 894–898, doi:10.1093/biosci/biab079, hdl:1808/30278, retrieved February 21, 2022
  96. ^ Hickel, Jason (6 December 2019). "The dark side of the Nordic model". Al Jazeera. Retrieved 3 July 2023. The first step is to abandon GDP as a measure of progress – as New Zealand Prime Minister Jacinda Ardern recently pledged to do – and focus instead on human well-being and ecology. There is a strong scientific consensus forming around this approach. A new paper signed by more than 11,000 scientists argues that high-income nations must shift to post-growth economic models if we are going to have any chance of preventing climate breakdown.
  97. ^ (in French) "La genèse du Réseau Objection de Croissance en Suisse", Julien Cart, in Moins!, journal romand d'écologie politique, 12, July–August 2014.
  98. ^ "Research & Degrowth". Retrieved 23 September 2014.
  99. ^ Declaration of the Paris 2008 Conference. Retrieved from: http://degrowth.org/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/Declaration-Degrowth-Paris-2008.pdf
  100. ^ "Décroissance économique pour la soutenabilité écologique et l'équité sociale". Archived from the original on 10 January 2016. Retrieved 16 May 2011.
  101. ^ "Degrowth Conference Barcelona 2010". Archived from the original on 10 April 2014. Retrieved 6 February 2014.
  102. ^ "International Conference on Degrowth in the Americas". Archived from the original on 2014-05-31. Retrieved 2013-04-06.
  103. ^ "International Degrowth Conference Venezia 2012". Retrieved 5 Dec 2012.
  104. ^ "5th International Degrowth Conference in Budapest". 2015-03-26. Retrieved 2018-01-31.
  105. ^ "Dialogues in turbulent times". Dialogues in turbulent times. Retrieved 2018-08-28.
  106. ^ "9th International Degrowth Conference".
  107. ^ Lietaert, Matthieu (2010). "Cohousing's relevance to degrowth theories". Journal of Cleaner Production. 18 (6): 576–580. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2009.11.016.
  108. ^ Housing for Degrowth: Principles, Models, Challenges and Opportunities. London: Routledge. 2019. ISBN 9780367358334.
  109. ^ 2nd Conference on Economic Degrowth for Ecological Sustainability and Social Ethic. 2010. Degrowth Declaration Barcelona 2010 and Working Groups Results. Retrieved from: http://barcelona.degrowth.org/ Archived 2014-04-10 at the Wayback Machine
  110. ^ Responsabilité, Innovation & Management. 2011. Décroissance économique pour l'écologie, l'équité et le bien-vivre par François SCHNEIDER. Retrieved from http://www.openrim.org/Decroissance-economique-pour-l.html Archived 2014-02-21 at the Wayback Machine
  111. ^ "Programme | Post-Growth 2018". 2018-03-30. Retrieved 2023-05-31.
  112. ^ a b Letters (2018-09-16). "The EU needs a stability and wellbeing pact, not more growth". The Guardian. ISSN 0261-3077. Retrieved 2023-05-31.
  113. ^ Balch, Oliver (2013-02-04). "Buen vivir: the social philosophy inspiring movements in South America". The Guardian. ISSN 0261-3077. Retrieved 2016-09-03.
  114. ^ Kothari, Ashish; Demaria, Federico; Acosta, Alberto (2014). "Buen Vivir, Degrowth and Ecological Swaraj: Alternatives to sustainable development and the Green Economy". Development. 57 (3–4): 362–375. doi:10.1057/dev.2015.24. S2CID 86318140.
  115. ^ a b Cederlöf, Gustav (2023). The Low-Carbon Contradiction: Energy Transition, Geopolitics, and the Infrastructural State in Cuba. Critical environments: nature, science, and politics. Oakland, California: University of California Press. ISBN 978-0-520-39313-4.
  116. ^ "Degrowth in movement(s)". Degrowth.info. Archived from the original on 2021-07-24.
  117. ^ Helfrich, Silke and David Bollier. 2014. Commons. In: Degrowth. A vocabulary for a new era. Giacomo D'Alisa, Federico Demaria, Giorgos Kalliseds. Oxon: Routledge
  118. ^ "Degrowth in movement(s)". Degrowth.info.[permanent dead link]
  119. ^ Asara, Viviana; Profumi, Emanuele; Kallis, Giorgos (2013). "Degrowth, Democracy and Autonomy". Environmental Values. 22 (2): 217–239. doi:10.3197/096327113X13581561725239. S2CID 144023408.
  120. ^ Kostakis, Vasilis; Niaros, Vasilis; Giotitsas, Chris (2023-06-30). "Beyond global versus local: illuminating a cosmolocal framework for convivial technology development". Sustainability Science. 18 (5): 2309–2322. doi:10.1007/s11625-023-01378-1. ISSN 1937-0709.
  121. ^ Hickel, Jason (September 23, 2020). "Degrowth and MMT: a thought experiment". jasonhickel.org. Retrieved July 9, 2023.
  122. ^ a b c Drews, Stefan; Antal, Miklós (2016). "Degrowth: A 'missile word' that backfires?". Ecological Economics. 126: 182–187. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2016.04.001.
  123. ^ Warriner, Amy Beth; Kuperman, Victor; Brysbaert, Marc (2013). "Norms of valence, arousal, and dominance for 13,915 English lemmas". Behavior Research Methods. 45 (4): 1191–1207. doi:10.3758/s13428-012-0314-x. PMID 23404613.
  124. ^ Meier, B. P.; Robinson, M. D. (2004-04-01). "Why the Sunny Side Is Up: Associations Between Affect and Vertical Position". Psychological Science. 15 (4): 243–247. doi:10.1111/j.0956-7976.2004.00659.x. ISSN 0956-7976. PMID 15043641. S2CID 31201262.
  125. ^ Lodge, Milton; Taber, Charles S. (2013). The Rationalizing Voter. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9781139032490. ISBN 9781139032490.
  126. ^ a b c van den Bergh, Jeroen C.J.M. (2011). "Environment versus growth — A criticism of "degrowth" and a plea for "a-growth"". Ecological Economics. 70 (5): 881–890. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2010.09.035.
  127. ^ Levy, Andrea; Gonick, Cy; Lukacs, Martin (January 22, 2014). "The greening of Noam Chomsky: a conversation". Canadian Dimension. Open Publishing. Retrieved March 27, 2019.
  128. ^ van den Bergh, Jeroen C. J. M. (2017). "A third option for climate policy within potential limits to growth". Nature Climate Change. 7 (2): 107–112. Bibcode:2017NatCC...7..107V. doi:10.1038/nclimate3113. hdl:1871.1/55d55cfa-2617-4e8a-b21c-fbc02ee19eea. ISSN 1758-678X.
  129. ^ L'écologie politique à l'ère de l'information, Ere, 2006, p. 68-69
  130. ^ https://monthlyreview.org/press/books/pb2181/, Monthly Review Press.
  131. ^ "Harmony and Ecological Civilization: Beyond the Capitalist Alienation of Nature". Monthly Review. June 2012.
  132. ^ Foster, John Bellamy (July 1, 2023). "Planned Degrowth: Ecosocialism and Sustainable Human Development". Monthly Review. Retrieved August 20, 2023.
  133. ^ Roth, Steffen. "Growth and function. A viral research program for next organizations" (PDF). International Journal of Technology Management.
  134. ^ Tunstall, E. (2015) 'Degrowth: Japan models design for steady state economies'. Swinburne University of Technology. https://www.swinburne.edu.au/news/2015/05/degrowth-japan-models-design-for-steady-state-economies/
  135. ^ Rosa, Hartmut; Dörre, Klaus; Lessenich, Stephan (2017). "Appropriation, Activation and Acceleration: The Escalatory Logics of Capitalist Modernity and the Crises of Dynamic Stabilization" (PDF). Theory, Culture & Society. 34 (1): 53–73. doi:10.1177/0263276416657600. ISSN 0263-2764. S2CID 148366804.
  136. ^ Luhmann, Niklas (1976). "The Future Cannot Begin: Temporal Structures in Modern Society". Social Research. 43: 130–152.
  137. ^ Büchs, Milena; Koch, Max (2019). "Challenges for the degrowth transition: The debate about wellbeing". Futures. 105: 155–165. doi:10.1016/j.futures.2018.09.002.
  138. ^ Baumann, A., S. Alexander and P. Burdon (2020) 'Land Commodification as a Barrier to Political and Economic Agency: A Degrowth Perspective' Journal of Australian Political Economy No. 86, pp. 379-405
  139. ^ Samuel Alexander and Alex Bauman, 'Access to land is a barrier to simpler, sustainable living' (22 August 2019) The Conversation.
  140. ^ a b Gomiero, Tiziano (2018). "Agriculture and degrowth: State of the art and assessment of organic and biotech-based agriculture from a degrowth perspective". Journal of Cleaner Production. 197: 1823–1839. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.03.237. S2CID 157265598.
  141. ^ Ferguson, Rafter Sass; Lovell, Sarah Taylor (2014). "Permaculture for agroecology: design, movement, practice, and worldview. A review" (PDF). Agronomy for Sustainable Development. 34 (2): 251–274. doi:10.1007/s13593-013-0181-6. ISSN 1774-0746. S2CID 15089504.
  142. ^ Müller, Adrian (2017). "Strategies for feeding the world more sustainably with organic agriculture" (PDF). Nature Communications. Springer Nature. 8 (1): 1290. Bibcode:2017NatCo...8.1290M. doi:10.1038/s41467-017-01410-w. PMC 5686079. PMID 29138387. Retrieved 17 June 2020.
  143. ^ Giampietro, Mario (2011-10-12). The Metabolic Pattern of Societies. doi:10.4324/9780203635926. ISBN 9780203635926.
  144. ^ Pinker, Steven (2019-01-03). Enlightenment Now. Penguin Books. ISBN 9780141979090. OCLC 1083713125.
  145. ^ a b Quilley, Stephen (2013). "De-Growth is Not a Liberal Agenda: Relocalisation and the Limits to Low Energy Cosmopolitanism". Environmental Values. 22 (2): 261–285. doi:10.3197/096327113X13581561725310. S2CID 144880469.
  146. ^ Nelson, Joel I. "Inequality in America: The Case for Post-Industrial Capitalism." Research in social stratification and mobility 18 (2001): 39–62. Web.
  147. ^ Rosalind Gill, Akane Kanai, Mediating Neoliberal Capitalism: Affect, Subjectivity and Inequality, Journal of Communication, Volume 68, Issue 2, April 2018, Pages 318–326. Web.
  148. ^ a b Kish, Kaitlin; Quilley, Stephen (2017). "Wicked Dilemmas of Scale and Complexity in the Politics of Degrowth". Ecological Economics. 142: 306–317. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2017.08.008.
  149. ^ Lynch, Kathleen, and Manolis Kalaitzake. "Affective and Calculative Solidarity: The Impact of Individualism and Neoliberal Capitalism." European journal of social theory 23.2 (2020): 239. Web.
  150. ^ Lynch, Kathleen, and Manolis Kalaitzake. "Affective and Calculative Solidarity: The Impact of Individualism and Neoliberal Capitalism." European journal of social theory 23.2 (2020): 245. Web.
  151. ^ Felski, Rita (2009). Gender of Modernity. Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674036796. OCLC 1041150387.
  152. ^ Cudd, Ann E., and Nancy Holmstrom. Capitalism, For and Against : a Feminist Debate. Cambridge University Press, 2011.
  153. ^ Doyal, Len; Gough, Ian (1991). Towards a political economy of degrowth. London, New York: Rowman & Littlefield International, Ltd. p. 77. ISBN 9781786608963.
  154. ^ a b c Büchs, Milena, and Max Koch. "Challenges for the Degrowth Transition: The Debate About Wellbeing." Futures : the journal of policy, planning and futures studies 105 (2019): 155–165. Web.
  155. ^ Kenneth J. Saltman, and David A. Gabbard. Education as Enforcement: The Militarization and Corporatization of Schools. Taylor and Francis, 2010. Web.
  156. ^ a b c Kallis, Giorgos, Christian Kerschner, and Joan Martinez-Alier. "The Economics of Degrowth." Ecological economics 84 (2012): 172–180. Web.
  157. ^ Akbulut, Bengi. "Degrowth." Rethinking Marxism 33.1 (2021): 98–110. Web.
  158. ^ Zywert, Katharine; Quilley, Stephen (2018). "Health systems in an era of biophysical limits: The wicked dilemmas of modernity". Social Theory & Health. 16 (2): 188–207. doi:10.1057/s41285-017-0051-4. S2CID 149177035.

Reference details edit

Further reading edit

External links edit