NOMINATE (scaling method)

NOMINATE (an acronym for Nominal Three-Step Estimation) is a multidimensional scaling application developed by US political scientists Keith T. Poole and Howard Rosenthal in the early 1980s to analyze preferential and choice data, such as legislative roll-call voting behavior.[1][2] In its most well-known application, members of the US Congress are placed on a two-dimensional map, with politicians who are ideologically similar (i.e. who often vote the same) being close together. One of these two dimensions corresponds to the familiar left–right political spectrum (liberal–conservative in the United States).

NOMINATE
W-NOMINATE coordinates of members of the 111th House of Representatives.
Developers
Keith T. Poole, University of Georgia
Howard Rosenthal, New York University

As computing capabilities grew, Poole and Rosenthal developed multiple iterations of their NOMINATE procedure: the original D-NOMINATE method, W-NOMINATE, and most recently DW-NOMINATE (for dynamic, weighted NOMINATE). In 2009, Poole and Rosenthal were the first recipients of the Society for Political Methodology's Best Statistical Software Award for their development of NOMINATE.[3] In 2016, the society awarded Poole its Career Achievement Award, stating that "the modern study of the U.S. Congress would be simply unthinkable without NOMINATE legislative roll call voting scores."[4]

Procedure

edit

The main procedure is an application of multidimensional scaling techniques to political choice data. Though there are important technical differences between these types of NOMINATE scaling procedures;[5] all operate under the same fundamental assumptions. First, that alternative choices can be projected on a basic, low-dimensional (often two-dimensional) Euclidean space. Second, within that space, individuals have utility functions which are bell-shaped (normally distributed), and maximized at their ideal point. Because individuals also have symmetric, single-peaked utility functions which center on their ideal point, ideal points represent individuals' most preferred outcomes. That is, individuals most desire outcomes closest their ideal point, and will choose/vote probabilistically for the closest outcome.

Ideal points can be recovered from observing choices, with individuals exhibiting similar preferences placed more closely than those behaving dissimilarly. It is helpful to compare this procedure to producing maps based on driving distances between cities. For example, Los Angeles is about 1,800 miles from St. Louis; St. Louis is about 1,200 miles from Miami; and Miami is about 2,700 miles from Los Angeles. From this (dis)similarities data, any map of these three cities should place Miami far from Los Angeles, with St. Louis somewhere in between (though a bit closer to Miami than Los Angeles). Just as cities like Los Angeles and San Francisco would be clustered on a map, NOMINATE places ideologically similar legislators (e.g., liberal Senators Barbara Boxer (D-Calif.) and Al Franken (D-Minn.)) closer to each other, and farther from dissimilar legislators (e.g., conservative Senator Tom Coburn (R-Okla.)) based on the degree of agreement between their roll call voting records. At the heart of the NOMINATE procedures (and other multidimensional scaling methods, such as Poole's Optimal Classification method[6]) are algorithms they utilize to arrange individuals and choices in low dimensional (usually two-dimensional) space. Thus, NOMINATE scores provide "maps" of legislatures.[7]

 
Keith T. Poole (left) and Howard Rosenthal (right), 1984.

Using NOMINATE procedures to study congressional roll call voting behavior from the First Congress to the present-day, Poole and Rosenthal published Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting[8] in 1997 and the revised edition Ideology and Congress[9] in 2007.

In 2009, Poole and Rosenthal were named the first recipients of the Society for Political Methodology's Best Statistical Software Award for their development of NOMINATE, a recognition conferred to "individual(s) for developing statistical software that makes a significant research contribution".[3] In 2016, Keith T. Poole was awarded the Society for Political Methodology's Career Achievement Award. The citation for this award reads, in part, "One can say perfectly correctly, and without any hyperbole: the modern study of the U.S. Congress would be simply unthinkable without NOMINATE legislative roll call voting scores. NOMINATE has produced data that entire bodies of our discipline—and many in the press—have relied on to understand the U.S. Congress."[4]

Dimensions

edit

Poole and Rosenthal demonstrate that—despite the many complexities of congressional representation and politics—roll call voting in both the House and the Senate can be organized and explained by no more than two dimensions throughout the sweep of American history. The first dimension (horizontal or x-axis) is the familiar left-right (or liberal-conservative) spectrum on economic matters. The second dimension (vertical or y-axis) picks up attitudes on cross-cutting, salient issues of the day (which include or have included slavery, bimetallism, civil rights, regional, and social/lifestyle issues). Rosenthal and Poole have initially argued that the first dimension refers to socio-economic matters and the second dimension to race-relations.[10] However, the often confusing and residual nature of the second dimension has led to the second dimension being largely ignored by other researchers.[11]

For the most part, congressional voting is uni-dimensional, with most of the variation in voting patterns explained by placement along the liberal-conservative first dimension. While the first dimension of the DW-NOMINATE score is able to predict results at 83% accuracy, the addition of the second dimension only increases accuracy to 85%.[10] Furthermore, the second dimension only provided a significant increase in accuracy for Congresses 1-99. As late as the 1990s, the second dimension was able to measure partisan splits in abortion and gun rights issues. However, a 2017 analysis found that since 1987, the votes of the US Congress had best fit a one-dimensional model, suggesting increasing party polarization after 1987.[12]

Interpretation of nominate scores

edit

For illustrative purposes, consider the following plots which use W-NOMINATE scores to scale members of Congress and uses the probabilistic voting model (in which legislators farther from the "cutting line" between "yea" and "nay" outcomes become more likely to vote in the predicted manner) to illustrate some major Congressional votes in the 1990s. Some of these votes, like the House's vote on President Clinton's welfare reform package (the Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Act of 1996) are best modeled through the use of the first (economic liberal-conservative) dimension. On the welfare reform vote, nearly all Republicans joined the moderate-conservative bloc of House Democrats in voting for the bill, while opposition was virtually confined to the most liberal Democrats in the House. The errors (those representatives on the "wrong" side of the cutting line which separates predicted "yeas" and predicted "nays") are generally close to the cutting line, which is what we would expect. A legislator directly on the cutting line is indifferent between voting "yea" and "nay" on the measure. All members are shown on the left panel of the plot, while only errors are shown on the right panel:

 

Economic ideology also dominates the Senate vote on the Balanced Budget Amendment of 1995:

 

On other votes, however, a second dimension (which has recently[when?] come to represent attitudes on cultural and lifestyle issues) is important. For example, roll call votes on gun control routinely split party coalitions, with socially conservative "blue dog" Democrats joining most Republicans in opposing additional regulation and socially liberal Republicans joining most Democrats in supporting gun control. The addition of the second dimension accounts for these inter-party differences, and the cutting line is more horizontal than vertical (meaning the cleavage is found on the second dimension rather than the first dimension on these votes) This pattern was evident in the 1991 House vote to require waiting periods on handguns:

 

Political ideology

edit

DW-NOMINATE scores have been used widely to describe the political ideology of political actors, political parties and political institutions.[13] For instance, a score in the first dimension that is close to either pole means that such score is located at one of the extremes in the liberal-conservative scale. So, a score closer to 1 is described as conservative whereas a score closer to −1 can be described as liberal. Finally, a score at zero or close to zero is described as moderate.[14][15]

Political polarization

edit
 
Political polarization in the United States House of Representatives.

Poole and Rosenthal (beginning with their 1984 article "The Polarization of American Politics"[16]) have also used NOMINATE data to show that, since the 1970s, party delegations in Congress have become ideologically homogeneous and distant from one another (a phenomenon known as "polarization"). Using DW-NOMINATE scores (which permit direct comparisons between members of different Congresses across time), political scientists have demonstrated the expansion of ideological divides in Congress, which has spurred intense partisanship between Republicans and Democrats in recent[when?] decades.[17][18][19][20][21][22][23] Contemporary political polarization has had important political consequences on American public policy, as Poole and Rosenthal (with fellow political scientist Nolan McCarty) show in their 2006 book Polarized America: The Dance of Ideology and Unequal Riches.[24]

Applications

edit

NOMINATE has been used to test, refine, and/or develop wide-ranging theories and models of the United States Congress.[25][26] In Ideology and Congress (pp. 270–271), Poole and Rosenthal agree that their findings are consistent with the "party cartel" model that Cox and McCubbins present in their 1993 book Legislative Leviathan.[27] Keith Krehbiel utilizes NOMINATE scores to determine the ideological rank order of both chambers of Congress in developing his "pivotal politics" theory,[28] as do Gary Cox and Matthew McCubbins in their tests of whether parties in Congress meet the conditions of responsible party government (RPG).[29]

NOMINATE scores have been used by popular media outlets like The New York Times and The Washington Post as a measure of the political ideology of political institutions and elected officials or candidates. Political blogger Nate Silver and his team at FiveThirtyEight have repeatedly used DW-NOMINATE scores to gauge the ideological location of major political figures and institutions.[30][31][32][33][34]

NOMINATE procedures and related roll call scaling techniques have also been applied to a number of other legislative bodies besides the United States Congress. These include the United Nations General Assembly,[35] the European Parliament[36] National Assemblies in Latin America,[37] and the French Fourth Republic.[38] Poole and Rosenthal note in Chapter 11 of Ideology and Congress (2007) that most of these analyses find that roll call voting is organized by only few dimensions (usually two): "These findings suggest that the need to form parliamentary majorities limits dimensionality."[39]

See also

edit

Further reading

edit

References

edit
  1. ^ Poole, Keith T.; Rosenthal, Howard (1983). "A Spatial Model for Legislative Roll Call Analysis" (PDF). GSIA Working Paper No. 5–83–84.
  2. ^ Poole, Keith T.; Rosenthal, Howard (1985). "A Spatial Model For Legislative Roll Call Analysis" (PDF). American Journal of Political Science. 29 (2): 357–384. doi:10.2307/2111172. JSTOR 2111172.
  3. ^ a b "Awards". The Society for Political Methodology. Archived from the original on 20 June 2010.
  4. ^ a b "The 2016 Political Methodology Career Achievement Award: Keith T. Poole". The Society for Political Methodology.
  5. ^ Description of NOMINATE Data.
  6. ^ Poole, Keith T. (2005). Spatial Models of Parliamentary Voting. Cambridge University Press. pp. 46–. ISBN 9780521851947. Retrieved 9 November 2012.
  7. ^ Ellenberg, Jordan (26 December 2001). "Mapping Congress' growing polarization". Slate. Retrieved 9 November 2012.
  8. ^ Poole, Keith T.; Rosenthal, Howard (1997). Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting. New York: Oxford University Press.
  9. ^ Poole, Keith T.; Rosenthal, Howard (2007). Ideology and Congress. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.
  10. ^ a b Everson, Phil; et al. (2009). "NOMINATE and American Political History: A Primer". Vote View Working Paper.
  11. ^ Bateman, D (2016). "Studies in American Political Development 2016". Studies in American Political Development. 30 (2): 147–171. doi:10.1017/S0898588X16000080. S2CID 31552378. Retrieved 1 February 2021.
  12. ^ Keith, Poole (12 January 2017). "The Collapse of the Voting Structure - Possible Big Trouble Ahead". Voteview Blog.
  13. ^ McCarty, Nolan (2011). "Measuring Legislative Preferences". In Schickler, Eric; Lee, Frances (eds.). Oxford Handbook of Congress. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  14. ^ Fleisher, Richard; Bond, John R. (2004). "The Shrinking Middle in the US Congress". British Journal of Political Science. 34 (3): 429–451. doi:10.1017/s0007123404000122. JSTOR 4092328. S2CID 153856544.
  15. ^ Poole, Keith T.; Rosenthal, Howard (1997). Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Appendix.
  16. ^ Poole, Keith T.; Rosenthal, Howard (1984). "The Polarization of American Politics" (PDF). Journal of Politics. 46 (4): 1061–79. doi:10.2307/2131242. JSTOR 2131242. S2CID 19531769.
  17. ^ Theriault, Sean M. (2008). Party Polarization in Congress. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  18. ^ Jacobson, Gary (2010). A Divider, Not a Uniter: George W. Bush and the American People. New York: Pearson Longman.
  19. ^ Abramowitz, Alan I. (2010). The Disappearing Center: Engaged Citizens, Polarization, and American Democracy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
  20. ^ Levendusky, Matthew (2009). The Partisan Sort: How Liberals Became Democrats and Conservatives Became Republicans. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
  21. ^ Baldassarri, Delia; Gelman, Andrew (2008). "Partisans without Constraint: Political Polarization and Trends in American Public Opinion". American Journal of Sociology. 114 (2): 408–46. doi:10.1086/590649. JSTOR 10.1086/590649. S2CID 222436264.
  22. ^ Fiorina, Morris P., with Samuel J. Abrams and Jeremy C. Pope. (2005). Culture War? The Myth of Polarized America. New York: Pearson Longman. ISBN 978-0205779888
  23. ^ Hetherington, Marc J. (2001). "Resurgent Mass Partisanship: The Role of Elite Polarization". American Political Science Review. 95 (3): 619–631. doi:10.1017/s0003055401003045. JSTOR 3118237. S2CID 14760921.
  24. ^ McCarty, Nolan; Poole, Keith T.; Rosenthal, Howard (2006). Polarized America: The Dance of Ideology and Unequal Riches. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. ISBN 978-0-262-13464-4.
  25. ^ Kiewiet, D. Roderick; McCubbins, Matthew D. (1991). The Logic of Delegation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
  26. ^ Shickler, Eric (2000). "Institutional Change in the House of Representatives, 1867–1998: A Test of Partisan and Ideological Power Balance Models". American Political Science Review. 94 (2): 269–288. doi:10.2307/2586012. JSTOR 2586012. S2CID 144490248.
  27. ^ Cox, Gary W.; McCubbins, Matthew D. (1993). Legislative Leviathan. Berkeley: University of California Press.
  28. ^ Krehbiel, Keith (1998). Pivotal Politics: A Theory of U.S. Lawmaking. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
  29. ^ Cox, Gary W.; McCubbins, Matthew D. (2005). Setting the Agenda: Responsible Party Government in the U.S. House of Representatives. New York: Cambridge University Press.
  30. ^ Azari, Julia (4 April 2016). "Are Sanders And Cruz Really Less 'Electable'?". FiveThirtyEight. Retrieved 24 December 2016.
  31. ^ Silver, Nate (10 April 2011). "An Imbalanced Budget Deal?". The New York Times. Retrieved 9 November 2012.
  32. ^ Silver, Nate (1 September 2010). "In Singling Out Murkowski, Tea Party Chose Wisely". The New York Times. Retrieved 9 November 2012.
  33. ^ Silver, Nate (29 April 2011). "How Liberal Is President Obama?". The New York Times. Retrieved 9 November 2012.
  34. ^ Klein, Ezra (30 August 2008). "The Republicans on the deficit commission are more conservative than the Democrats are liberal". The Washington Post. Archived from the original on 14 October 2012. Retrieved 9 November 2012.
  35. ^ Voeten, Erik (2001). "Outside Options and the Logic of Security Council Action". American Political Science Review. 95 (4): 845–858. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.372.7699. doi:10.1017/s000305540101005x. JSTOR 3117717.
  36. ^ Hix, Simon; Noury, Abdul; Roland, Gérard (2006). "Dimensions of Politics in the European Parliament" (PDF). American Journal of Political Science. 50 (2): 494–511. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2006.00198.x. JSTOR 3694286. S2CID 56074538.
  37. ^ Mogernstern, Scott. (2004). Patterns of Legislative Politics: Roll-Call Voting in Latin America and the United States. New York: Cambridge University Press.
  38. ^ Rosenthal, Howard; Voeten, Erik (2004). "Analyzing Roll Calls with Perfect Spatial Voting: France 1946–1958". American Journal of Political Science. 48 (3): 620–632. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.488.6466. doi:10.2307/1519920. JSTOR 1519920.
  39. ^ Poole and Rosenthal, Ideology and Congress, p. 295.
edit