Specific performance

(Redirected from Specific Performance)

Specific performance is an equitable remedy in the law of contract, in which a court issues an order requiring a party to perform a specific act, such as to complete performance of a contract.[1] It is typically available in the sale of land law, but otherwise is not generally available if damages are an appropriate alternative. Specific performance is almost never available for contracts of personal service, although performance may also be ensured through the threat of proceedings for contempt of court.

An injunction, often concerning confidential information or real property, is a type or subset of specific performance and is one of the more commonly-used forms of specific performance. While specific performance can be in the form of any type of forced action, it is usually to complete a previously established transaction, thus being the most effective remedy in protecting the expectation interest of the innocent party to a contract. It is usually the opposite of a prohibitory injunction, but there are mandatory injunctions that have a similar effect to specific performance and these kinds of distinctions are often difficult to apply in practice or even illusory.

At common law, a claimant's rights were limited to an award of damages. Later, the court of equity developed the remedy of specific performance instead, should damages prove inadequate. Specific performance is often guaranteed through the remedy of a right of possession, giving the plaintiff the right to take possession of the property in dispute.[citation needed]

As with all equitable remedies, orders of specific performance are discretionary, so their availability depends on their appropriateness in the circumstances. Such orders are granted when damages are not an adequate remedy and in some specific cases such as land (which is regarded as unique).

Exceptional circumstances

edit

An order of specific performance is generally not granted if any of the following is true:

  • Specific performance would cause severe hardship to the defendant.
  • The contract was unconscionable.
  • Money damages are an adequate remedy.[2][3]
  • The claimant has misbehaved (unclean hands).
  • Specific performance is impossible.
  • Performance consists of a personal service [4]
  • The contract is too vague to be enforced.
  • The contract was terminable at will (meaning either party can renege without notice).
  • The contract required constant supervision.[6]
  • Mutuality was lacking in the initial agreement of the contract.
  • The contract was made for no consideration.
  • The contract at issue was void or unenforceable. The exception to this (in equity) is in relation estoppel or part performance.[7]
  • Where an injunction to restrain an employee from working for a rival employer will be granted even though specific performance cannot be obtained. The leading case is Lumley v Wagner, which is an English decision.[8]

Additionally, in England and Wales, under s. 50 of the Senior Courts Act 1981, the High Court has discretion to award a claimant damages in lieu of specific performance (or an injunction). Such damages will normally be assessed on the same basis as damages for breach of contract, namely to place the claimant in the position he would have been had the contract been carried out.

Summary of the Law in Australia

edit

In summary of the law of specific performance in Australia:[9]

When a Court Will Order Specific Performance:

  1. Valid and Enforceable Contract: There must be a legally binding agreement between the parties.
  2. Breach or Threatened Breach: There must be a breach or threatened breach of the agreement by the defendant.
  3. Uniqueness of the Property: The subject of the contract, especially in real estate transactions, must be unique to such an extent that monetary damages would not be a sufficient remedy.
  4. Irreparable Harm: The aggrieved party would suffer irreparable harm if specific performance were not granted, such as in cases where real property’s unique value cannot be compensated with money alone.
  5. Inadequacy of Common Law Damages: Common law damages must be an inadequate remedy for the breach.
  6. Party is Ready, Willing, and Able to Perform: The party seeking specific performance must demonstrate their willingness and ability to fulfill their own obligations under the contract.

When a Court Will Not Order Specific Performance:

  1. Monetary Damages are Adequate: If the harm caused by the breach can be adequately compensated with money, specific performance is unlikely to be ordered.
  2. Contract is Not Clear or Enforceable: If the contract terms are ambiguous, not agreed upon by all parties, or the contract is otherwise unenforceable, specific performance will not be granted.
  3. Speculative Purposes: If the purpose of enforcing the contract is speculative in nature, such as for anticipated profits from development or resale, courts may be hesitant to order specific performance.
  4. Requires Continuous Supervision: If fulfilling the contract would require ongoing supervision by the court, specific performance may be deemed inappropriate.
  5. Lack of Uniqueness: In cases not involving unique assets like real estate, where substitute performance or goods are readily available, specific performance may not be ordered.

Examples

edit

In practice, specific performance is most often used as a remedy in transactions regarding land, such as in the sale of land where the vendor refuses to convey title. One traditional justification for this position is that land is unique and that there is not another legal remedy available to put the non-breaching party in the same position had the contract been performed.[10] However, modern decisions in at least one common law jurisdiction (Ontario) have argued that "uniqueness" is only a proxy for the real conceptual justification of specific performance, which is that it is fundamentally an open-ended rule of justice and will be awarded wherever the plaintiff shows that the land in question, rather than damages, better serves justice between the parties in all the circumstances.[11]

However, the limits of specific performance in other contexts are narrow. Moreover, performance based on the personal judgment or abilities of the party on which the demand is made is rarely ordered by the court. The reason behind it is that the forced party will often perform below the party's regular standard, when it is in the party's ability to do so. Monetary damages are usually given instead.

Traditionally, equity would only grant specific performance with respect to contracts involving chattels where the goods were unique in character, such as art, heirlooms, and the like. The rationale behind this was that with goods being fungible, the aggrieved party had an adequate remedy in damages for the other party's non-performance.

In the United States, Article 2 of the Uniform Commercial Code displaces the traditional rule in an attempt to adjust the law of sales of goods to the realities of the modern commercial marketplace. If the goods are identified to the contract for sale and in the possession of the seller, a court may order that the goods be delivered over to the buyer upon payment of the price. This is termed replevin. In addition, the Code allows a court to order specific performance where "the goods are unique or in other proper circumstances", leaving the question of what circumstances are proper to be developed by case law. The relief of Specific Performance is an equitable relief which is usually remedial or protective in nature. In the civil law (the law of continental Europe and much of the non English speaking world) specific performance is considered to be the basic right. Money damages are a kind of "substitute specific performance." Indeed, it has been proposed that substitute specific performance better explains the common law rules of contract as well, see (Steven Smith, Contract Law, Clarenden Law ).

In English law, in principle reparation must be done in specie unless another remedy is ‘more appropriate’.[12]

edit

There is an ongoing debate in the legal literature regarding the desirability of specific performance. Economists, generally, take the view that specific performance should be reserved to exceptional settings, because it is costly to administer and may deter promisors from engaging in efficient breach. Professor Steven Shavell, for example, famously argued that specific performance should only be reserved to contracts to convey property and that in all other cases, money damages would be superior.[13] In contrast, many lawyers from other philosophical traditions take the view that specific performance should be preferred as it is closest to what was promised in the contract.[14] There is also uncertainty arising from empirical research whether specific performance provides greater value to promisees than money damages, given the difficulties of enforcement.[15]

Law and economics

edit

In contract theory, economists have compared specific performance to at-will contracts.[16] Suppose that a seller and a buyer have agreed to trade a good in the future. In the case of specific performance, delivery of the good can be mandated by the court, while in the case of at-will contracting, the seller always has the right to walk away from the contract. Hart and Moore (1988) have shown that if only at-will contracts are enforceable, then the parties have insufficient incentives to make relationship-specific investments.[17] Subsequently, several authors such as Aghion et al. (1994) have shown that the underinvestment problem (sometimes called the hold-up problem) can be solved if specific performance contracts are feasible.[18] However, these conclusions rely on the assumption that there are no information asymmetries. Schmitz (2022) has pointed out that if the seller may gain an informational advantage over the buyer after the contract has been signed, then at-will contracts may sometimes be preferable from an economic efficiency point-of-view.[19]

See also

edit

References

edit
  1. ^ "specific performance". LII / Legal Information Institute. Retrieved 2023-07-30.
  2. ^ Dougan v Ley [1946] HCA 3, (1946) 71 CLR 142, High Court (Australia).
  3. ^ Loan Investment Corporation of Australasia v Bonner [1969] UKPC 33 [1969] NZPC 1, [1970] NZLR 724, Privy Council (on appeal from New Zealand).
  4. ^ Patrick Stevedores Operations No 2 Pty Ltd v Maritime Union of Australia [1998] HCA 32, (1998) 195 CLR 1 (4 May 1998), High Court (Australia).
  5. ^ (c)making an agreement binding on the consumer whereas provision of services by the seller or supplier is subject to a condition whose realisation depends on his own will alone, http://www.legislation.gov.uk/uksi/1999/2083/schedule/2/made
  6. ^ Co-Operative Insurance Society Ltd v Argyll Stores (Holdings) Ltd [1997] UKHL 17, [1998] AC 1, House of Lords (UK).
  7. ^ Goldsbrough, Mort and Co Ltd v Quinn [1910] HCA 20, (1910) 10 CLR 674, High Court (Australia).
  8. ^ Lumley v Wagner [1852] EWHC J96 (Ch), (1852) 64 ER 1209, High Court of Chancery (England and Wales).
  9. ^ Davis, Wayne (4 February 2024). "Contract Law 101 – Specific Performance".
  10. ^ "Real Estate Specific Performance Dispute Attorney | Schorr Law". Schorr Law, A Professional Corporation. Retrieved 2022-02-03.
  11. ^ "John E. Dodge Holdings Inc. v. 805062 Ontario Ltd., 2001 CanLII 28012 (Ontario Superior Court of Justice)". CanLII, Canadian Legal Information Institute. 2001.
  12. ^ Beswick v Beswick [1967] UKHL 2, [1968] AC 58, House of Lords (UK) per Lord Pearce.
  13. ^ Shavell, Steven (2005-11-01). "Specific Performance versus Damages for Breach of Contract". Rochester, NY. doi:10.2139/ssrn.868593. SSRN 868593. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  14. ^ Shiffrin, Seana (2007-01-24). "The Divergence of Contract and Promise". Rochester, NY. SSRN 959211. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  15. ^ Arbel, Yonathan A. (2015-01-16). "Contract Remedies in Action: Specific Performance". West Virginia Law Review. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1641438. S2CID 156489028. SSRN 1641438. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  16. ^ Fares, M'hand (2006). "Renegotiation Design and Contract Solutions to the Hold-Up Problem". Journal of Economic Surveys. 20 (5): 731–756. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6419.2006.00266.x. ISSN 0950-0804. S2CID 155061589.
  17. ^ Hart, Oliver; Moore, John (1988). "Incomplete Contracts and Renegotiation". Econometrica. 56 (4): 755–785. doi:10.2307/1912698. hdl:1721.1/63746. ISSN 0012-9682. JSTOR 1912698.
  18. ^ Aghion, Philippe; Dewatripont, Mathias; Rey, Patrick (1994). "Renegotiation Design with Unverifiable Information". Econometrica. 62 (2): 257–282. doi:10.2307/2951613. ISSN 0012-9682. JSTOR 2951613.
  19. ^ Schmitz, Patrick W. (2022). "How (Not) to Purchase Novel Goods and Services: Specific Performance versus At-Will Contracts". Economic Journal. 132 (647): 2563–2577. doi:10.1093/ej/ueac024.

Sources

edit
  • A Kronman, ‘Specific Performance’ (1978) 45 University of Chicago LR 351
  • S Schwartz, ‘The Case for Specific Performance’ (1979) 89 Yale Law Journal 271
  • I Macneil, ‘Efficient Breach of Contract: Circles in the Sky’ (1982) 68 Virginia LR 947


edit