In functional analysis, a branch of mathematics, a selection theorem is a theorem that guarantees the existence of a single-valued selection function from a given set-valued map. There are various selection theorems, and they are important in the theories of differential inclusions, optimal control, and mathematical economics.[1]

Preliminaries edit

Given two sets X and Y, let F be a set-valued function from X and Y. Equivalently,   is a function from X to the power set of Y.

A function   is said to be a selection of F if

 

In other words, given an input x for which the original function F returns multiple values, the new function f returns a single value. This is a special case of a choice function.

The axiom of choice implies that a selection function always exists; however, it is often important that the selection have some "nice" properties, such as continuity or measurability. This is where the selection theorems come into action: they guarantee that, if F satisfies certain properties, then it has a selection f that is continuous or has other desirable properties.

Selection theorems for set-valued functions edit

The Michael selection theorem[2] says that the following conditions are sufficient for the existence of a continuous selection:

The approximate selection theorem[3] states the following:

Suppose X is a compact metric space, Y a non-empty compact, convex subset of a normed vector space, and Φ: X →   a multifunction all of whose values are compact and convex. If graph(Φ) is closed, then for every ε > 0 there exists a continuous function f : XY with graph(f) ⊂ [graph(Φ)]ε.

Here,   denotes the  -dilation of  , that is, the union of radius-  open balls centered on points in  . The theorem implies the existence of a continuous approximate selection.

Another set of sufficient conditions for the existence of a continuous approximate selection is given by the Deutsch–Kenderov theorem,[4] whose conditions are more general than those of Michael's theorem (and thus the selection is only approximate):

  • X is a paracompact space;
  • Y is a normed vector space;
  • F is almost lower hemicontinuous, that is, at each  , for each neighborhood   of   there exists a neighborhood   of   such that  ;
  • for all x in X, the set F(x) is nonempty and convex.

In a later note, Xu proved that the Deutsch–Kenderov theorem is also valid if   is a locally convex topological vector space.[5]

The Yannelis-Prabhakar selection theorem[6] says that the following conditions are sufficient for the existence of a continuous selection:

The Kuratowski and Ryll-Nardzewski measurable selection theorem says that if X is a Polish space and   its Borel σ-algebra,   is the set of nonempty closed subsets of X,   is a measurable space, and   is an  -weakly measurable map (that is, for every open subset   we have  ), then   has a selection that is  -measurable.[7]

Other selection theorems for set-valued functions include:

Selection theorems for set-valued sequences edit

References edit

  1. ^ Border, Kim C. (1989). Fixed Point Theorems with Applications to Economics and Game Theory. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 0-521-26564-9.
  2. ^ Michael, Ernest (1956). "Continuous selections. I". Annals of Mathematics. Second Series. 63 (2): 361–382. doi:10.2307/1969615. hdl:10338.dmlcz/119700. JSTOR 1969615. MR 0077107.
  3. ^ Shapiro, Joel H. (2016). A Fixed-Point Farrago. Springer International Publishing. pp. 68–70. ISBN 978-3-319-27978-7. OCLC 984777840.
  4. ^ Deutsch, Frank; Kenderov, Petar (January 1983). "Continuous Selections and Approximate Selection for Set-Valued Mappings and Applications to Metric Projections". SIAM Journal on Mathematical Analysis. 14 (1): 185–194. doi:10.1137/0514015.
  5. ^ Xu, Yuguang (December 2001). "A Note on a Continuous Approximate Selection Theorem". Journal of Approximation Theory. 113 (2): 324–325. doi:10.1006/jath.2001.3622.
  6. ^ Yannelis, Nicholas C.; Prabhakar, N. D. (1983-12-01). "Existence of maximal elements and equilibria in linear topological spaces". Journal of Mathematical Economics. 12 (3): 233–245. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.702.2938. doi:10.1016/0304-4068(83)90041-1. ISSN 0304-4068.
  7. ^ V. I. Bogachev, "Measure Theory" Volume II, page 36.