Monotone likelihood ratio

In statistics, the monotone likelihood ratio property is a property of the ratio of two probability density functions (PDFs). Formally, distributions and bear the property if

A monotonic likelihood ratio in distributions and

The ratio of the density functions above is monotone in the parameter so satisfies the monotone likelihood ratio property.

that is, if the ratio is nondecreasing in the argument .

If the functions are first-differentiable, the property may sometimes be stated

For two distributions that satisfy the definition with respect to some argument we say they "have the MLRP in " For a family of distributions that all satisfy the definition with respect to some statistic we say they "have the MLR in "

Intuition edit

The MLRP is used to represent a data-generating process that enjoys a straightforward relationship between the magnitude of some observed variable and the distribution it draws from. If   satisfies the MLRP with respect to  , the higher the observed value  , the more likely it was drawn from distribution   rather than   As usual for monotonic relationships, the likelihood ratio's monotonicity comes in handy in statistics, particularly when using maximum-likelihood estimation. Also, distribution families with MLR have a number of well-behaved stochastic properties, such as first-order stochastic dominance and increasing hazard ratios. Unfortunately, as is also usual, the strength of this assumption comes at the price of realism. Many processes in the world do not exhibit a monotonic correspondence between input and output.

Example: Working hard or slacking off edit

Suppose you are working on a project, and you can either work hard or slack off. Call your choice of effort   and the quality of the resulting project   If the MLRP holds for the distribution of   conditional on your effort  , the higher the quality the more likely you worked hard. Conversely, the lower the quality the more likely you slacked off.

1: Choose effort   where   means high effort, and   means low effort.
2: Observe   drawn from   By Bayes' law with a uniform prior,
 
3: Suppose   satisfies the MLRP. Rearranging, the probability the worker worked hard is
 
which, thanks to the MLRP, is monotonically increasing in   (because   is decreasing in  ).

Hence if some employer is doing a "performance review" he can infer his employee's behavior from the merits of his work.

Families of distributions satisfying MLR edit

Statistical models often assume that data are generated by a distribution from some family of distributions and seek to determine that distribution. This task is simplified if the family has the monotone likelihood ratio property (MLRP).

A family of density functions   indexed by a parameter   taking values in an ordered set   is said to have a monotone likelihood ratio (MLR) in the statistic   if for any  

  is a non-decreasing function of  

Then we say the family of distributions "has MLR in  ".

List of families edit

Family      in which   has the MLR   
  Exponential          observations
  Binomial          observations
  Poisson          observations
  Normal       if   known,   observations

Hypothesis testing edit

If the family of random variables has the MLRP in   a uniformly most powerful test can easily be determined for the hypothesis   versus  

Example: Effort and output edit

Example: Let   be an input into a stochastic technology – worker's effort, for instance – and   its output, the likelihood of which is described by a probability density function   Then the monotone likelihood ratio property (MLRP) of the family   is expressed as follows: For any   the fact that   implies that the ratio   is increasing in  

Relation to other statistical properties edit

Monotone likelihoods are used in several areas of statistical theory, including point estimation and hypothesis testing, as well as in probability models.

Exponential families edit

One-parameter exponential families have monotone likelihood-functions. In particular, the one-dimensional exponential family of probability density functions or probability mass functions with

 

has a monotone non-decreasing likelihood ratio in the sufficient statistic   provided that   is non-decreasing.

Uniformly most powerful tests: The Karlin–Rubin theorem edit

Monotone likelihood functions are used to construct uniformly most powerful tests, according to the Karlin–Rubin theorem.[1] Consider a scalar measurement having a probability density function parameterized by a scalar parameter   and define the likelihood ratio   If   is monotone non-decreasing, in   for any pair   (meaning that the greater   is, the more likely   is), then the threshold test:

 
where   is chosen so that  

is the UMP test of size   for testing   vs.  

Note that exactly the same test is also UMP for testing   vs.  

Median unbiased estimation edit

Monotone likelihood-functions are used to construct median-unbiased estimators, using methods specified by Johann Pfanzagl and others.[2][3] One such procedure is an analogue of the Rao–Blackwell procedure for mean-unbiased estimators: The procedure holds for a smaller class of probability distributions than does the Rao–Blackwell procedure for mean-unbiased estimation but for a larger class of loss functions.[3]: 713 

Lifetime analysis: Survival analysis and reliability edit

If a family of distributions   has the monotone likelihood ratio property in  

  1. the family has monotone decreasing hazard rates in   (but not necessarily in  )
  2. the family exhibits the first-order (and hence second-order) stochastic dominance in   and the best Bayesian update of   is increasing in  .

But not conversely: neither monotone hazard rates nor stochastic dominance imply the MLRP.

Proofs edit

Let distribution family   satisfy MLR in   so that for   and  

 

or equivalently:

 

Integrating this expression twice, we obtain:

1. To   with respect to  
 

integrate and rearrange to obtain

 
2. From   with respect to  
 

integrate and rearrange to obtain

 

First-order stochastic dominance edit

Combine the two inequalities above to get first-order dominance:

 

Monotone hazard rate edit

Use only the second inequality above to get a monotone hazard rate:

 

Uses edit

Economics edit

The MLR is an important condition on the type distribution of agents in mechanism design and economics of information, where Paul Milgrom defined "favorableness" of signals (in terms of stochastic dominance) as a consequence of MLR.[4] Most solutions to mechanism design models assume type distributions that satisfy the MLR to take advantage of solution methods that may be easier to apply and interpret.

References edit

  1. ^ Casella, G.; Berger, R.L. (2008). "Theorem 8.3.17". Statistical Inference. Brooks / Cole. ISBN 0-495-39187-5.
  2. ^ Pfanzagl, Johann (1979). "On optimal median unbiased estimators in the presence of nuisance parameters". Annals of Statistics. 7 (1): 187–193. doi:10.1214/aos/1176344563.
  3. ^ a b Brown, L.D.; Cohen, Arthur; Strawderman, W.E. (1976). "A complete class theorem for strict monotone likelihood ratio with applications". Annals of Statistics. 4 (4): 712–722. doi:10.1214/aos/1176343543.
  4. ^ Milgrom, P.R. (1981). "Good news and bad news: Representation theorems and applications". The Bell Journal of Economics. 12 (2): 380–391. doi:10.2307/3003562.