Brams–Taylor procedure

The Brams–Taylor procedure (BTP) is a procedure for envy-free cake-cutting. It explicated the first finite procedure to produce an envy-free division of a cake among any positive integer number of players.[1]

History edit

In 1988, prior to the discovery of the BTP, Sol Garfunkel contended that the problem solved by the theorem, namely n-person envy-free cake-cutting, was among the most important problems in 20th century mathematics.[2]

The BTP was discovered by Steven Brams and Alan D. Taylor. It was first published in the January 1995 issue of American Mathematical Monthly,[3] and later in 1996 in the authors' book.[4]

Brams and Taylor hold a joint US patent from 1999 related to the BTP.[5]

Description edit

The BTP divides the cake part-by-part. A typical intermediate state of the BTP is as follows:

  • A part of the cake, say  , is divided in an envy-free way among all partners.
  • The rest of the cake, say  , remains undivided, but -
  • One partner, say Alice, has an Irrevocable Advantage (IA) over another partner, say Bob, with respect to  . This means that, regardless of how   is divided, even if we give   entirely to Bob, Alice still doesn't envy Bob.

As an example of how an IA can be generated, consider the first stage of the Selfridge–Conway discrete procedure:

  • Alice divides the cake to 3 parts she considers equal; let's call the parts  .
  • Bob trims the piece he considers largest (say,  ) to make it equal to the second-largest; let's call the trimmings   and the trimmed piece  .
  • Charlie chooses a piece out of  ; then Bob chooses (he must take   if it is available); and lastly Alice.

After this stage is done, all the cake except   is divided in an envy-free way. Additionally, Alice now has an IA over whoever took  . Why? because Alice took either   or  , and both of them are equal to   in her opinion. So, in Alice's opinion, whoever took   can also have   – this will not make her envy.

If we want to make sure that Alice gets an IA over a specific player (e.g. Bob), then a much more complicated procedure is required. It successively divides the cake to smaller and smaller pieces, always giving Alice a piece that she values more than Bob's, so that an IA is maintained. This might take an unbounded time – depending on the exact valuations of Alice and Bob.

Using the IA procedure, the main BTP procedure creates IAs for all ordered pairs of partners. For example, when there are 4 partners, there are 12 ordered pairs of partners. For each such pair (X,Y), we run a sub-procedure which guarantees that partner X has an IA over partner Y. After every partner has an IA over every other partner, we can just give the remainder to an arbitrary partner and the result is an envy-free division of the entire cake.

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ "Dividing the Spoils". Discover Magazine. 1995-03-01. Archived from the original on 2012-03-10. Retrieved 2015-05-02.
  2. ^ More Equal than Others: Weighted Voting Archived 2019-12-05 at the Wayback Machine Sol Garfunkel. For All Practical Purposes. COMAP. 1988
  3. ^ Brams, S. J.; Taylor, A. D. (1995). "An Envy-Free Cake Division Protocol". The American Mathematical Monthly. 102 (1): 9–18. doi:10.2307/2974850. JSTOR 2974850.
  4. ^ Brams, Steven J.; Taylor, Alan D. (1996). Fair division: from cake-cutting to dispute resolution. Cambridge University Press. pp. 138–143. ISBN 0-521-55644-9.
  5. ^ US patent 5983205, Steven J. Brams & Alan D. Taylor, "Computer-based method for the fair division of ownership of goods", issued 1999-11-09, assigned to New York University